• Nie Znaleziono Wyników

Minimum Wage in Poland: Economy-wide or Regionally Differentiated?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Minimum Wage in Poland: Economy-wide or Regionally Differentiated?"

Copied!
22
0
0

Pełen tekst

(1)

FOLIA OECONOMICA 248, 2011

Aleksandra Rogut

*

Zbigniew ółkiewski

**

MINIMUM WAGE IN POLAND:

ECONOMY-WIDE OR REGIONALLY DIFFERENTIATED?

INTRODUCTION

Minimum wage in Poland, set uniformly across all the regions, has increased

substantially over last years and especially after Poland’s accession to EU in

1

2004. There are plans, especially of trade unions, to increase it further to 50% of

average wage, following recommendations of the International Labour

Organisation

2

(ILO).

This tendency reflects to a large extent EU social and employment policy

priorities, with minimum wage envisaged to serve three objectives (European

Foundation 2007):

−reducing poverty and wage inequality,

−protection of vulnerable workers,

−encouraging labour market integration ( ‘making work pay’).

While labour organizations and social partners tend to highlight social

security and protection impact of minimum wage legislation, economists are

quite often skeptical whether this is adequate and effective tool of alleviating

poverty and income inequalities. They rather emphasise potential danger of

setting minimum wage at the level above the productivity of some groups of

workers what has adverse effect on the demand for these employees. Moreover,

while this objection gives an argument for the certain restraint in augmenting

minimum wage, even its modest rise may be harmful to employment if there is

* Dr, Uniwersytet Łódzki and Narodowy Bank Polski. ** Dr, Narodowy Bank Polski.

1 As of 2010, minimum wage is by almost 60% higher than in 2004. During the same period, average salary increased by approximately 40%. As a result, minimum to average wage ratio has increased during this time from 36% to 42%.

2 After: Kłos B., Płaca minimalna w pastwach członkowskich Unii Europejskiej (Minimum

Wage in the Member States of European Union), Kancelaria Sejmu, Biuro Studiów i Ekspertyz

(2)

considerable regional variation in average wage and therefore minimum wage

may be binding in some low wage regions. Adjustment of minimum wage to

local labour market conditions through its regional differentiation is therefore

a way to neutralize to some extent negative effects of minimum wage legislation.

Poland is a country with considerable regional wage inequalities

3

and also with

substantial diversification of unemployment rates across regions and employees

groups (especially, with respect to skill, education etc). These characteristics of

labour market provide rationale for considering setting of minimum wage at

regional basis. This opinion was put forward in this year

4

OECD Economic

Survey of Poland 2010 as the following policy recommendation: ‘The minimum

wage should not be increased relative to the average wage but be differentiated

across regions, based on local labour market conditions.’

5

. This

recommendation looks plausible against the background of the stylized facts on

the labour market in Poland mentioned above. However, OECD documents do

not refer to any up-to-date analysis of the impact of minimum wage on labour

market performance in Poland, especially in regional dimension. Indeed,

literature on this issue for Poland is not very extensive, leaving the question of

assessment of minimum wage policy in fact unfounded on empirical verification.

The main motivation of this study is to verify the hypothesis that minimum

wage may have negative impact on employment in Poland, at least for some

workers groups and regions. Plan of the paper is as follows. In section

2 theoretical considerations on the potential impact of minimum wage on labour

market performance will be presented and most important papers on Poland and

countries of the region will be quoted. Section 3 will be devoted to discussion of

some regional labour market statistics in Poland, important from the point of

view of potential impact of minimum wage. In section 4 econometric models

will be defined, data used described and results discussed. Section 5 will

complete the paper with conclusions.

3 In 2008, the average wage in the low end of wage distribution (Warmisko-mazurskie voivodship) was not more than 2/3 of the wage in the most affluent Mazowieckie voivodship (NUTS-2). More on regional wage and income inequalities in Poland in: Rogut and Tokarski (2005), Wyszyski 2008.

4 Questions of policies with respect to minimum wage in Poland were raised by OECD in previous Surveys, eg. in 2004 and 2006.

(3)

IMPACT OF MINIMUM WAGE ON LABOUR MARKET: THEORY AND EMPIRICAL RESULTS

There is no clear-cut answer on the impact of the increase of minimum wage

on labour market performance, except for the stylized, textbook-type

neoclassical model with homogenous labour and symmetrical information. In

this case, rise in the minimum wage above the competitive equilibrium level,

produces decline in demand for labour and increase in the supply, thus leading to

the rising (involuntary) unemployment. However, in more ‘realistic’ neoclassical

model with heterogenous labour and products, the result (sign of employment

adjustment) depends on the elasticities of substitution across different types of

workers and cross-elasticities of demand across different types of goods

6

. When

the models are further complicated and more labour market imperfections are

being introduced, the results of minimum wage legislation are ex ante

ambiguous, both theoretically and empirically. For instance, in the model with

monopsony in factor markets, rise in the minimum wage has generally

non-monotonic impact on employment. It may lead to increase in employment if the

new minimum wage is lower than competitive level (adjustment along the

supply curve) but it may reduce employment if government sets minimum wage

at higher than competitive equilibrium level

7

(adjustment along the demand

curve). Also in the labour market model with search frictions, an impact of

minimum wage increase is in general indeterminate. I may lead to higher

employment if market is dominated by employers (the market wage is low). But

if market wages are higher, this will reduce firms’ incentives to create jobs,

number of vacancies will shrink what will discourage workers from searching

for the job and finally employment will be reduced

8

. Also efficiency wage

theory gives an argument that rising minimum wage above competitive

equilibrium level does not necessarily creates barrier to employment. According

to this approach, higher wages generate to workers incentives to increase their

productivity (eg., wages determine productivity) what finally results in increased

and not decreased employment as potential reaction to minimum wage rise

9

.

6 D. Neumark, W. Wascher, Minimum Wages and Employment, IZA Discussion Paper No. 2570, Bonn 2007.

7 G. Rocheteau, M. Tasci, The Minimum Wage and the Labor Market, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, 2007.

8 Rocheteau and Tasci – op. cit.

9 Manning A. (1995), How Do We Know that Real Wages Are too High?, The Quarterly

(4)

The main body of both theoretical and empirical literature focuses on impact

of minimum wage legislation on employment. General specification of the

model applied for this purpose may be formulated as follows

10

:

ER = f(MW, X) + e (1)

where:

E – Remployment variable,

MW – minimum wage variable,

X – vector of control variables (economic activity, labour supply, institutional

variables etc.),

E – unobserved error term.

Usually both employment and minimum wage are expressed in relative

terms, eg. as employment-population ratio and minimum-to-average wage

11

ratio, respectively. As for the control variables, some measure of a business

cycle position (eg., GDP, output gap etc.) is used to take into account demand

factors behind employment fluctuations. Supply factors like some demographic

variable (eg. working age population or specific age group, like youths,

developments) and institutional variables are also taken as explanatory variables.

The latter represent the features of the labour market that may potentially affect

sensitivity of employees and employers to minimum wage legislation, like the

unemployment benefit replacement rate or union density.

In the earlier research on minimum wage effect, equation (1) was being

estimated econometrically as time-series model. Subsequent work along this line

brought an understanding that basic model should be modified to take into

account residual autocorrelation (eg., inclusion of interactions between the

seasonal dummies and a trend and also modelling the error as a first-order

autoregressive or AR(1) process

12

). Since 1990’s combined time series and cross

section data analyses became more and more popular together with the progress

in panel data econometrics techniques. Panel data models proved to be

particularly useful in the analyses of impact of minimum wage legislation across

regions. However, the key problem with this type of models is whether the

results based on panel data models (pooled regional time series) are robust to

relaxation of assumptions underlying the use of the panel-data methodology,

especially on the stability of the regression coefficients both over time and

10 Eg., C. Brown, C. Gilroy, A. Kohen, The Effect of the Minimum Wage on Employment and

Unemployment, Journal of Economic Literature, 20, 1982, pp. 487-528.

11 Quite often relative minimum wage is measured by the so called Kaitz index that is defined as the ratio of the minimum to the average wage multiplied by the percent of persons covered by the minimum wage (eg, see Neumark and Wascher – op. cit.).

12 See: W. Lee, S. Suardi, Minimum Wages and Employment:Reconsidering the Use of a

(5)

across regions. For instance, McDonald and Myatt

13

have shown that these

assumption are problematic for the large part of the panel econometrics literature

on minimum wage for Canada and therefore the validity of the negative

employment effect of minimum wages, claimed unanimously by this literature,

may be questioned.

As for the other potential effects of minimum wage

14

, impact on labour force

participation is ambiguous. The net effect will result from the interplay of the

two countervailing forces: employees withdrawing from the labour market as

a reaction to falling employment because of minimum wage rise (‘discouraged

worker’ effect) and workers entering labour market in hope for better paid job

(“added worker” effect). As for the impact on unemployment, it will again be

interplay of “discouraged” versus “added” worker effect, with empirical

literature pointing to expected smaller rise in unemployment vis-à-vis drop in

employment

15

. Minimum wage legislation may have also impact on employment

of other workers, and especially those just above the minimum wage (so called

‘spillover effect’). This effect will mean increase of the demand for workers just

above the minimum if they are substitutes of the employees earning minimum

wage and decrease if they are complements of workers at minimum wage.

Similar mechanism may be expected for the workers earning just below the

minimum wage. The ‘spillover’ (or ‘ripple’) effect may be also defined and

observed with respect to wages. Minimum wage legislation will modify not only

wage of the group of workers directly affected but the final effect may

materialize throughout the wage distribution as firms try to restore at least some

of their former wage structure. Impact of the minimum wage has been also

studied in the context of training and human capital formation

16

. As in case of

other labour market variables, overall effect is ambiguous. Training effort may

be reduced if workers are to pay for it but may be augmented if higher minimum

wage encourages employees to acquire additional training to improve their

productivity. Also impact of the minimum wage on school enrollment results

13 J. T. McDonald, A. E. Myatt, The Minimum Wage Effect on Youth Employment in Canada:

Testing the Robustness of Cross-Province Panel Studies, mimeo, Department of Economics,

University of New Brunswick, 2004.

14 EG., see review publications: M. Gunderson, Miminum Wages In Canada: Theory, Evidence

And Policy, Human Resources and Skills Development Canada 2005; Neumark and Wascher

(2007) – op. cit.

15 Gunderson – op. cit.

16 Eg., see: R. P. Cubitt, S. P. Hargreaves-Heap, Minimum Wage Legislation, Investment and

Human Capital, cottish Journal of Political Economy, 1999, 46(2):135–157; D. Acemoglu,

J. S. Pischke, The Structure of Wages and Investment in General Training, NBER Working Paper Series, no. 6357, 1998.

(6)

from interplay of counteracting forces

17

. On the one hand, potential workers may

stay in school longer when jobs are decreasing but on the other hand, they may

leave school earlier since opportunity cost of education (the forgone income

from a higher wage job) increased. Many researchers have made an effort to

verify positive impact of the minimum wage legislation on wage inequality,

usually anticipated when introducing this type of regulation

18

. Theoretical

considerations lead to presumption that impact of minimum wage on wage

inequality is in general ambiguous. Reduction of inequality, desired by the

supporters of minimum wage legislation, may result from the fact that some

low-wage (minimum low-wage) jobs will disappear with rising minimum low-wage, certain

low-wage earners may improve their productivity, and also positive spillover

effects (on wages near minimum) may materialize. But there will be also

countervailing forces, leading to the increase of inequality (especially in the long

run) if minimum wage rise discourage training and other human capital

formation. Summarizing empirical literature on this issue, mostly on Canada

and USA, Gunderson

19

concludes that while minimum wages seem to reduce

wage inequality, their positive effect on poverty is problematic, given adverse

employment effects of the minimum wage legislation (pp. 30-31).

General conclusions from the large body of empirical studies (mostly on US

and Canada) may be formulated as follows

20

:

−for mostly examined employment effect of minimum age, the majority of the

literature find adverse impact of the minimum wage legislation. Eg.,

according to the Neumark and Wascher

21

, two thirds of 102 studies surveyed

resulted in negative employment effects, and only 8 positive,

−if significant impact of minimum age on employment was found, then

respective elasticities were dispersed along wide range of estimates,

−adverse labour market effects of minimum wage legislation concentrate in

particular segments, mostly low-skilled young workers,

17 Eg., D. Neumark, W. Wascher, Minimum Wage Effects on Employment and School

Enrollment, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 13 (1995) pp.199-206; Gunderson 2005 – op. cit.

18 Eg., see: D. Card, J. DiNardo, Skill-Biased Technological Change and Rising Wage

Inequality: Some Problems and Puzzles, Journal of Labor Economics 20, 2000, p. 733-783;

S. Bazen, The Impact of the Regulation of Low Wages on Inequality and Labour-Market

Adjustment: A Comparative Analysis, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 16, No. 1 (Spring

2000), pp. 57-69; T. Lemieux, Increased Residual Wage Inequality: Composition Effects, Noisy Data or Rising Demand for Skill, University of British Columbia 2005, Department of Economics Working Paper.

19 Gunderson – op. cit.

20 See: Neumark, Wascher – op. cit.; Gunderson – op. cit. 21 Neumark Wascher – op. cit.

(7)

−results are less clear for other potential effects of minimum wage legislation,

eg. labour force participation, training and education, wage inequality etc.

Similarly to the diversity of the results for the main world economies, most of

the scarce literature on the countries of Central and Eastern Europe reveals

negative impact of minimum wage legislation on employment but the results are

not unanimous. For instance, for the Czech republic Fialova and Mysikova

22

find

significant adverse consequences of the minimum wage for labor market

(unemployment rate) while Gottvald et al.

23

and Eriksson and Pytlikova

24

claim

that impact of minimum wage on employment is unclear, and effect on wages

turned out to be positive. For Hungary, Halpern et al.

25

report sizeable adverse

impact of minimum wage increase on employment and Kertesi and Köll

26

confirm these results in case of employment opportunities in the small enterprise

sector.

Research for Poland on labour market consequences of minimum wage

legislation has not produced, as for other countries, commonly accepted

conclusions. Melnyk

27

found strong negative impact of minimum wage rise on

employment and unemployment rates. He also identified a large degree of

regional disparity with respect to employment elasticity of minimum wage.

Conclusions of the study of Suchecki

28

were as follows: there is strong adverse

employment and unemployment effect of minimum wage increase especially for

22 K. Fialova, M. Mysikova, Minimum Wage: Labour Market Consequences in the Czech

Republic, IES Working Paper: 6/2009, Charles University in Prague, 2009.

23 J. Gottvald, J. Han lová, M. Pytlikova, Minimum Wage and Its Impact on Wage Distribution,

Unemployment and Hours Worked, In: Gottvald J. et al. (Eds), Determinants of individual pay and firms pay structures in the Czech and Slovak Republics 2002, Ostrava, VŠB-TU.

24 T. Eriksson, M. Pytlikova, Firm-level Consequences of Large Minimum-wage Increases in

the Czech and Slovak Republics 2004, Labour, 18(1), p. 75-103.

25 L. Halpern, M. Koren, G. K rösi, J. Vincze J., A minimálbér költségvetési hatásai

[Budgetary effects of the rise in the minimum wage], Közgazdasági Szemle, Series 51, April 2004,

pp. 325-345, as discussed in: D. Benedyk, M. Rigó, Á. Scharle, P. Szabó, Increases in The

Minimum Wage in Hungary, 2001–06, Ministry of Finance Working Paper No. 16, January 2006.

26 G. Kertesi, J. Köll , A 2001.évi minimálbér-emelés foglalkoztatási következményei

[Employment effects of the 2001 rise in the minimum wage], Közgazdasági Szemle, Series 51,

April 2004, pp. 293-324, as discussed in: D. Benedyk, M. Rigó, Á. Scharle, P. Szabó, Increases in

The Minimum Wage in Hungary, 2001–06, Ministry of Finance Working Paper No. 16, January

2006.

27 A. M. Melnyk, The Minimum Wage and Unemployment in Poland: Lessons for Cuba’s

Transition, Cuba in Transition, ASCE 1996.

28 B. Suchecki, Narzdzia kształtowania dochodu godziwego w Polsce (Policies of decent

income in Poland), in: S. Borkowska (ed.), Wynagrodzenia godziwe. Koncepcja i pomiar, IPISS,

(8)

young workers (15-24 years), and much weaker for other groups. Ruzik

29

found

that minimum wage might constraint employment of unskilled workers. Boni

30

(ed.) claimed that it is not only level of minimum wage that matters but also

alternative sources of income in case of employees and non-wage labour cost for

employers (especially for low educated and young workers). The most

extensive study on impact of minimum wage on labour market by Jacukowicz

31

,

based on survey of firms (ended with the conclusion that there was no impact of

minimum wage on unemployment and no need of regional differentiation of

minimum wage. Also Golnau

32

concluded his study with the general supposition

that minimum wage has rather insignificant impact on employment and

unemployment. If the adverse effects of raising minimum wage emerge, they are

restricted to low-wage workers (eg. youths) and these effects are rather small.

STYLIZED FACTS ON REGIONAL PICTURE OF LABOUR MARKET IN POLAND

MINIMUM WAGE IN POLAND

Minimum monthly wage in Poland is negotiated on an annual basis within

the Tripartite Commission for Social and Economic Affairs, composed of

representatives of government, employees’ and employers’. Then upon the

results of the negotiations, government sets the minimum as legally binding for

all the wage contracts in the subsequent year. If there is no consensus within the

Tripartite Commission, the minimum wage is set unilaterally by the government.

Minimum wage legislation provides exceptional treatment for the first-time

entrants to the labour market. For this group, wages may be set at 80% of the

statutory minimum wage in the first year of their employment and at 90% in the

second. As of 2007, approximately 4% of Polish employees received the

minimum remuneration.

29 A. Ruzik, Minimalne wynagrodzenie – analiza wpływu na zatrudnienie w Polsce, (Minimum

wage – an analysis of impact on employment in Poland), Instytut Pracy i Spraw Socjalnych,

Polityka Społeczna nr 1/2007, Warszawa (in Polish).

30 M. Boni M (ed.), Elastyczny rynek pracy w Polsce. Jak sprosta temu wyzwaniu?(Elastic

labour market in Poland. How to meet this Challenge?, Zeszyty BRE Bank – CASE Nr. 73, 2004.

31 Z. Jacukowicz, Analiza minimalnego wynagrodzenia za prac (Analysis of minimum

remuneration for work), IPiSS, Warszawa 2007, seria "Studia i Monografie" (in Polish).

32 W. Golnau, Znaczenie płacy minimalnej dla funkcjonowania rynku pracy (The impact of the

minimum wage on the labour market in Poland), Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Gdaskiego, 2007,

(9)

DISTRIBUTION OF MINIMUM WAGE RECIPIENTS

Looking at the distribution of minimum wage recipients in Poland we may

notice that it concerns mostly young people (below 25 years old, see Figure 1).

About 35% of employed in the age group 15-17 in 2004 received minimum

wage.

Figure 1. Minimum wage employees by age (%, 2004)

Source: Jacukowicz, Analiza minimalnego wynagrodzenia za prac... – op. cit.

Figure 2 Minimum wage employees by education (%, 2004)

(10)

Figure 3. Minimum wage employees by firm size (%, 2004)

Source: Jacukowicz, Analiza minimalnego wynagrodzenia za prac... – op. cit.

Figure 4 Minimum wage employees by sector (%, 2004)

Source: Jacukowicz, Analiza minimalnego wynagrodzenia za prac... – op. cit.

As for the education level, minimum wage earners are mostly the least skilled

workers with vocational training (‘zasadnicze zawodowe’) of whom 7,9%

receive minimum wage and those with at most basic education (‘podstawowe

i niepełne podstawowe’) of whom 6,3% are affected by minimum wage (see

Figure 2). Moreover, looking at the distribution of minimum wage by firm class,

we may notice that minimum wage recipients are employed mostly in small

enterprises (below 9 or between 10 and 19 employees, see Figure 3). The firms

paying minimum wages are mostly located in services (see Figure 4), especially

in trade (sector G) and hotels and restaurants (sector H). What is worth

emphasizing, these are the sectors in which there is the highest percentage of

(11)

production in the shadow economy (see Figure 5). This is apparently factor that

may complicate accurate measurement of minimum wage employment coverage

and also may put bias on estimated effect of minimum wage legislation.

Figure 5. Shadow economy by sector (%, 2004)

Source: Jacukowicz, Analiza minimalnego wynagrodzenia za prac... – op. cit.

Figure 6. Minimum wage employees by region (%, 2004)

Source: Jacukowicz, Analiza minimalnego wynagrodzenia za prac... – op. cit.

Minimum wage recipients are also not evenly distributed among regions. The

highest share of them are employed in lodzkie and warminsko-mazurskie

(12)

regions (see Figure 6). The lowest share of minimum wages workers were

noticed in mazowieckie and opolskie regions.

CHANGES OF MINIMUM WAGE IN POLAND

Looking at the changes of minimum wage in Poland during the last ten years

we may notice significant changes. The level of minimum wage increased from

650 PLN in 1999 to 1276 PLN in 2009, ie. almost doubled (see Figure 7).

Figure 7. Minimum wage in Poland, 1999–2010 (PLN)

Source: Ministry of Labour and Social Policy (www.mpips.gov.pl).

The minimum wage changes were not uniform over time. The most

significant rises were concentrated at the beginning of the analyzed period

(about 8% per year in 2000–2001) and then in 2008 and 2009 (respectively

about 20.3% and 13.3% per year) – see Figure 8.

0 200 400 600 800 1000 1200 1400 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

(13)

Figure 8. Minimum wage in Poland, 1999–2010 (yoy, %)

Source: Ministry of Labour and Social Policy (www.mpips.gov.pl).

Wage developments in Poland during analysed period and in particular rises

in the minimum wage resulted in the changes of its ratio with respect to the

average wage in Poland (see Figure 9).

Figure 9. Minimum to average wage ratio in Poland, in 2002–2008 (%)

Source: www.stat.gov.pl, own calculations.

In 1999 the minimum to average wage ratio in Poland was about 38%. In

subsequent years this ratio fluctuated to have decreased to 33% in 2007. The

0,0% 5,0% 10,0% 15,0% 20,0% 25,0% 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 0,32 0,33 0,34 0,35 0,36 0,37 0,38 0,39 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008

(14)

strong increase in minimum wage in Poland in 2008 has led to increase in

minimum to average ratio to 38% and 41% in 2009 (own estimates based on the

official data).

REGIONAL DIVERSITY OF WAGES IN POLAND

Looking at the regional distribution of wages among regions we can see

significant differences. These differences result to a great extent from variation

in regional structure of production (eg., see Rogut and Tokarski

33

). The highest

wages are observed in the financial sector and in some industries (mostly

mining).

The highest wages in Poland are observed for mazowieckie (capital) region

(128-129% of average wage in Poland in 2002–2008) where financial services

are concentrated. Wages above the average are observed also in slaskie (103% in

2002–2008), the region with considerable share of mining industry. Relatively

high wages (around average) are noted in dolnoslaskie (mining industry) and

pomorskie (shipyard industry).

33 A. Rogut, T. Tokarski, Determinanty regionalnego zrónicowania płac w Polsce

(Determinants of regional wage differentiation in Poland), Ekonomista, nr 1, 2005, s. 75

(15)

Figure 10. Average monthly gross wage by voivodship, 1999–2008 (PLN)

Source: www.stat.gov.pl.

The lowest wages in Poland are observed in rural regions of the eastern part

of Poland (podkarpackie with 83-84% of average wage in Poland) and also in

western regions of Poland with high structural unemployment

(warminsko-mazurskie, lubuskie, kujawsko-pomorskie, 83-86% of average wage in Poland).

Looking at the regional diversity of wages in Poland (the average level of

coefficient of variation in the analysed period around 0.12) we may however

notice that it’s scale is very much affected by very high wages in mazowieckie.

Without mazowieckie in the sample the value of coefficient of variation

decreases significantly (to 0.6-0,7). The second observation is that regional

diversity of wages in Poland has been persistent during the analysed period.

0,00 500,00 1000,00 1500,00 2000,00 2500,00 3000,00 3500,00 4000,00 4500,00 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 dolnoĞlaskie kujawsko-pomorskie lubelskie

lubuskie łódzkie małopolskie

mazowieckie opolskie podkarpackie

podlaskie pomorskie Ğląskie

ĞwiĊtokrzyskie warmiĔsko-mazurskie wielkopolskie zachodniopomorskie

(16)

REGIONAL DIVERSITY OF MINIMUM TO AVERAGE RATIO

The uniform economy-wide minimum wage in Poland on the one hand and

considerable regional diversity of average wage by regions result in the

significant variation of regional minimum to average wage ratio (see Figure 11).

Figure 11. Minimum to average wage ratio by voivodship, 1999–2008 (%)

Source: www.stat.gov.pl and www.mpips.gov.pl, own calculations.

For instance, if we analyse the data for 2008, then with the average ratio of

38%, regional statistics varied considerably. In the most affluent mazowieckie

voivodship minimum wage was less than 27% of average wage in this region,

while in poor podkarpackie and warminsko-mazurskie voivodships this ratio was

about 42%. The differentiation of comparable size was persistent during the

analysed period (see Figure 11). In particular, we may notice the following

stable in time groupings of regions:

−Mazowieckie – the lowest relation of minimum to average wage (0.25-0.28),

−Slaskie, Pomorskie, Dolnoslaskie – relatively low (0.32-0.36),

−Podkarpackie – the highest ratio (0.39-0.43).

According to other studies

34

, regional variation in wages may be to a large

extent explained by the differences in labour productivity across the regions and

34 eg., see Rogut, Tokarski – op. cit.

.24 .28 .32 .36 .40 .44 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08

W R_DOLN W R_KUJA W R_LODZ

W R_LUBE W R_LUBU W R_MALO

W R_MAZO W R_OPOL W R_PODK

W R_PODL W R_POMO W R_SLAS

W R_SW IE W R_W ARM W R_W IEL

(17)

territorial inequalities of wages and incomes are even more sharp at more

disaggregated level, like powiat

35

(county). Namely, regions (voivodships) with

low average wage levels are at the same time characterised by low productivity.

And especially in those regions minimum wage, high with respect to the regional

average, might be the factor limiting demand for labour since cost of employing

low productive worker would in some cases outweigh the product of his work.

MODEL AND THE RESULTS

MODEL

Trying to analyze the impact of minimum wage level on employment in

Poland on the regional level we estimate the parameters the following equation,

which follows general specification used predominantly in the literature (see

section 2 above):

it it it it

w

X

Empl

=

α

0

+

α

1

min

+

α

2

+

ξ

(2)

where:

it

Empl – employment rate on regional labour market i in Poland at time t,

it

w min – minimum to average wage ratio on regional labour market i in Poland

at time t,

it

X – vector of control variables (proxy for production, school enrolment,

employment structure, institutional variables),

it

ξ

– error term.

Trying to analyse the impact of minimum wages on employment rate we

have to remember that the regional differences in the latter are due to many other

factors (among others, the level of economic activity, the school enrolment ratio,

the production structure (especially in Polish case the share of labour in

agriculture sector)) as well as the institutional variables which may have impact

on the level of regional employment, like unemployment benefit to average

wage ratio.

Mostly because of the problems with long individual time-series data for the

regions, we had to use the panel analyses option. All panel data series are

stationary. Due to availability of the statistical data we used annual data.

35 See also: R. Wyszyski, Regionalne dysproporcje dochodowe w Polsce (Regional income

inequalities in Poland) [w:] Wzrost gospodarczy a bezrobocie i nierównoci w podziale dochodu,

(18)

As the aim of the paper is to assess the impact of minimum wages on

employment on regional labour markets, especially among the most vulnerable

groups, our dependent variables are: employment rate in the age group 15-64,

employment rate among young (age 15-24) and employment rate among low

skilled, as measured by lower than the secondary education level.

The explanatory variables vector includes: minimum to average wage ratio,

different measures of economic activity, enrolment ratio among 20-24 years old

and the share of labour in agriculture sector.

ESTIMATION RESULTS

Results for the employment rate of the most general population of employees

(age group 15-64) as dependent variable do not confirm the hypothesis that

minimum wage limited overall employment in Poland in the analysed period.

The elasticity of employment rate with respect to minimum to average wage

ratio is very low (0,006-0,04) and not significant (see Table 1).

These results indicate that employment rate in Poland is lower in regions with

higher school enrolment (SE), and moreover that the employment rate in Poland

seems to be negatively and significantly correlated with the unemployment

benefit ratio (ZAS).

Table 1

Estimation results for the dependent variable: employment rate 15-64

Employment rate 15-64 Wr 0.043 0.038 0.014 0.006 0.006 PKB spbm 0.019 Nio 0.022 Nisp 0.004 Sdto -0.002 Sdnz 0.000111 SE -0.217*** -0.223*** -0.218*** -0.217*** -0.218*** LR -0.016 -0.017 -0.016 -0.016 -0.0159 ZAS -0.643*** -0.647*** -0.658*** -0.661*** -0.660***

CSFE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

TFE No No No No No

(19)

However, if we take the results of next series of estimations in which impact

of minimum wage on employment of potentially vulnerable group of young

workers is investigated (15-24 age group), we can confirm a significant and

negative sign of parameter for employment rate with respect to minimum wage

(see Table 2).

Table 2

Estimation results for the dependent variable: employment rate 15-24

Employment rate 15-24 Wr -0.416 -0.311 -0.413 -0.522* -0.529* PKB spbm 0.0591 Nio 0.149* Nisp 0.062 Sdto 0.083 Sdnz 0.047 SE -0.791*** -0.830 -0.798*** -0.815*** -0.810*** LR 0.00457 0.000370 0.007 0.006 0.006 ZAS -1.762*** -1.722*** -1.778*** -1.802*** -1.808***

CSFE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

TFE No No No No No

Skor.R2 0.756 0.759 0.755 0.754 0.754

Elasticity of employment rate with respect to minimum to average ratio

estimated for this model is consistent with the literature and close to the high end

of the range

36

. This result mean that 10 percent increase in the minimum wage

potentially reduces employment of this group of workers by around five percent.

Additionally, the results indicate that employment rate among young is, as

might be expected, negatively and in significant way correlated with enrolment

ratio as well as the ratio of unemployment benefit to average wage.

As for the results for another vulnerable group: the least skilled workers, we

can not confirm the hypothesis that minimum wage limited employment among

36 As earlier literature consensus was -0.1 to -0.3 range (see Neumar, Wascher – op. cit.), later research based on more sophisticated methods and more recent data found larger adverse employment effects of minimum wage, belonging to the range from -0.3 to -0.6 (eg., M. Campolieti, T. Fang, M. Gunderson, Minimum Wage Impacts on Youth Employment Transitions, 1993–1999, Canadian Journal of Economics. Vol. 38, No. 1 (February), pp. 81-104.).

(20)

this group in Poland. The value of elasticity is positive and not (or very low)

significant (see Table 3).

Table 3

Estimation results for the dependent variable: employment rate of the least skilled employees

Employment rate of the least skilled

Wr 0.280* 0.262 0.256 0.256* 0.259* PKB spbm 0.011 Nio 0.00289 Nisp 0.000127 Sdto -0.0321 Sdnz -0.0172 SE -0.358*** -0.360*** -0.359*** -0.353 -0.355*** LR 0.070* 0.070* 0.070* 0.070* 0.070* ZAS -0.725*** -0.733*** -0.736*** -0.740*** -0.737***

CSFE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

TFE No No No No No

Skor.R2 0.819 0.818 0.819 0.819 0.819

When interpreting this result one should remember that it may be distorted by

the relatively large ‘shadow economy’ in Poland

37

that covers mostly low-skilled

segment of the labour market. As emphasized before, shadow economy is

concentrated in trade, and hotels and restaurants sections when the education

level of employees is relatively low and salaries are also less than economy-wide

average

38

. These facts are also confirmed by the results of the comprehensive

study

39

on shadow economy in Poland according to which most of the shadow

economy employees are the least-skilled blue collar workers. As a consequence,

we are not able to measure correctly neither their employment nor wages in this

case. And more important, the mechanism of adjustment of employment to the

37 ‘Shadow economy’ is officially estimated at ca. 15% in 2007 (GUS 2009).

38 See GUS 2010, Zatrudnienie i wynagrodzenia w gospodarce narodowej w I kwartale 2010 r. (Employment, Wages And Salaries in National Economy. First Quarter 2010), Warszawa (in Polish).

39 MPiPS, Przyczyny pracy nierejestrowanej, jej skala, charakter i skutki społeczne. Wybrane

informacje z bada (The Causes of the the Non-Registered Employment, it’s Nature and Social Consequences. Some survey results), Ministerstwo Pracy i Polityki Społecznej, Warszawa 2007,

(21)

minimum wage regulation may be seriously disturbed for this group of workers.

This problem is known in the literature on labour market impact of minimum

wage regulation. For instance, Neumark and Wascher

40

maintain that in the

countries with the large informal sector ‘there are serious concerns about the

enforcement of and compliance with minimum wage laws’ (p. 105).

CONCLUSIONS

In this article we have tried to verify the hypothesis that minimum wage may

be the factor reducing demand for labour in Poland as for instance put forward

lately and many times before by the OECD in its recommendations on labour

market policy in Poland. We used regional (voivodship) data in our estimations

to account for the fact that minimum wage may be binding at least in some

regions and therefore there are grounds for regional minimum wage

differentiation as also recommended. Our results show that minimum wage

legislation might be responsible for reducing employment opportunities in

Poland, 1999–2008, only for the group of young (age 15-24 years) workers.

Elasticity of employment to minimum wage is consistent with the international

literature and should be assessed as rather high. No significant adverse effect of

minimum wage on employment has been demonstrated for the total employment

or for the least-skilled segment of the labour market. As for the latter, we

suppose that shadow economy factor, not taken into account in our study, might

have seriously disturbed the results.

As also typical for other countries, our results suggest that minimum wage

legislation is not very important for the whole labour market performance but it

may create adverse effects for some vulnerable groups, like youths. The other

feature of our research, parallel to the international experience, is sensitivity of

the results to model specification. Therefore we plan to refine our study by the

sensitivity analysis of the stability of parameter estimates in time and across

space. We will also experiment with some other specifications of explanatory

variables. And since we only touched upon the question of regional

differentiation of minimum wage, we will try to add regional analyzes, using

time series models and seemingly unrelated regressions methodology.

As for the potential policy recommendations, the main one would be word of

caution on further increases of minimum wage, from the point of view of

employment prospects of young workers end especially graduates.

Unemployment rate in this group is already much higher than average

(respectively, 24.6% vs. 10.6%, I quarter 2010, LFS) and – as our results show –

(22)

situation may be aggravated by the future minimum wage rises

41

. Other

vulnerable group of the least-skilled workers seem to adjust to minimum wage

legislation by transferring their work to the shadow economy. Other results that

give reason for policy recommendation are consistently adverse impact of school

enrolment and unemployment benefit to wage ratio. As for the former, it partly

reflects the increasing propensity to educate among younger generations but it

may also be a sign of barriers to employment of students at the labour market in

Poland. Relatively low participation by students in the labour market in Poland

was pointed out in some previous OECD studies. Therefore, further reforms of

both higher education system and labour market to increase economic activity of

students will alleviate negative impact of minimum wage on employment, other

things equal. As for the latter factor (unemployment benefit to wage ratio), our

results suggest that unemployment benefits should not be further increased so as

not to deteriorate the work prospects of some vulnerable groups at the labour

market. As for the supposition of adjusting the level of minimum wage to local

labour market conditions, there is further analyses required to validate or reject

it.

(Summary)

The aim of the paper is to verify the hypothesis that minimum wage may have negative impact on employment in Poland, at least for some workers groups and regions. After having reviewed theoretical literature on minimum wage and having discussed stylized facts on minimum wage in Poland, the authors define econometric model to check the impact of minimum wage on employment in Poland and then discuss the results. The main conclusion of the study is that while minimum wage legislation is not very important for the whole labour market performance it may create adverse effects to employment of some vulnerable groups like young workers.

41 According to the government proposal, the minimum wage is going to increase by 5.2% since January 1, 2011.

Cytaty

Powiązane dokumenty

Voor veiligheid bij de Nieuwe Waterweg zijn voor de hele lange termijn twee opties in beeld: het afsluiten van de Nieuwe waterweg door een dam/sluis en dijkversterkingen in

Due to the fact that modern man faces dilemmas about how to have and be in a specific reality, then in the second chapter there will appear a space to show those

The study examines causal relationships, in the Granger sense, between minimum wage and selected labour market indicators in Poland between the years 2002 and 2019.. The pe-

Bez wątpienia sytuacji życiowej jednostki — jej celów, świadomości itd. — nie wyznacza jedynie i wyłącznie grupa czy klasa, do której dany człowiek należy, gdyż grtipa ta

Fenomen wzajemnych zależności Innego/Obcego i konfliktu może być ciekawym spojrzeniem na problematykę konfliktów w gospodarowaniu przestrzenią i zasobami Ziemi, gdyż

Przedsiębiorstwo nie podejmie działań, które nie mają dla niego ekonomicznego sensu (re- prezentowanego w niniejszej analizie przez NPV), dlatego istotne jest analizowanie takich

The gross minimum wage at the time amounted to 1,317 PLN and the net wage amounted to 948.15 PLN, with the total cost of labour incurred by an employer amounting to 1,560.39 PLN,

The next part of the book is an edited text of an abbreviated variant of the  Old Church Slavonic translation of the Ecloga (p. 187–192), found in the Old Russian copies