• Nie Znaleziono Wyników

Stress Tests and Liquidity Crisis in the Banking System

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Stress Tests and Liquidity Crisis in the Banking System"

Copied!
14
0
0

Pełen tekst

(1)

Julián Llorent, María del Carmen

Melgar, José Antonio Ordaz, Flor

María Guerrero

Stress Tests and Liquidity Crisis in

the Banking System

Equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics and Economic Policy 8/2, 31-43

(2)

E

QUILIBRIUM

Quarterly Journal of Economics and Economic Policy

VOLUME 8 ISSUE 2, 2013 ISSN 1689-765X

Julián Llorent, María del Carmen Melgar

José Antonio Ordaz, Flor María Guerrero

Universidad Pablo de Olavide, Spain

Stress Tests and Liquidity Crisis

in the Banking System

JEL Classification: G21, G33

Keywords: Stress tests, Liquidity, Banking bailouts

Abstract: The paper´s aim is to contribute to the debate on the impact of stress test

on banking system liquidity. Due to the theoretical character of the problem, the used methodology is a set of results from research and theoretical works about how the attempts to increase system solvency could lead into a greater lack of liquidity.

Introduction

After World War I, Moulton (1918a, pp. 484-508; 1918b, pp. 638-663; 1918c, 705-731) explained his shiftability theory, in which, under normal conditions, liquidity is not as much a maturity problem as an assets transfer problem to other banks and ‘raise cash’. If a bank with problems can get help from other better off, is not so necessary to meet deadlines-appeal. Thus, banks rely on assets that can be transferred to other banks before ma-turity to meet its cash requirements (Summers 1975). However, in August 2007, the subprime crisis created serious liquidity problems for the interbank market. Banks, unsure about the depth of the problems on other banks’ bal-ance sheets, were simply unwilling to lend to each other without substantial

© Copyright Institute of Economic Research & Polish Economic Society Branch in Toruń Date of submission: April 14, 2013; date of acceptance: May 27, 2013

Contact: jllojur@upo.es, mcmelhir@upo.es, jaordsan@upo.es, fguecas@upo.es, Universidad Pablo de Olavide, Carretera de Utrera Km 1, 41013 Sevilla, Spain

(3)

accommodations for counterparty risks (Brunetti et al. 2011, 2053-2083). So, a set of measures was necessary to establish which banks and how deeply had been damaged by the crisis, and to ensure transparency in the bank data provided.

In this context, supervisors brought stress testing up as the only way out from the confidence crisis that underlies the liquidity crisis consequence of a prior regulatory crisis. The stress test’s objectives were laudable: to strengthen the financial system by forcing banks to hold adequate equity and to convince markets about the solvency of banks. Unfortunately, situations such as the Irish banks, which approved the 2010´s stress tests and forced the country to be rescued a few months later, and recent banking bailouts (e.g. Dexia, Bankia) led to a criticism in media about the tests rigour (The Finan-cial Times 2011; Finch et al. 2011; Burke 2011). In this sense, half a decade since the crisis started, a lack of confidence over banks information and li-quidity crisis in markets there remains. This leads us to wonder whether the stress tests really have favoured or have harmed (by an unwanted feedback effect) the lack of liquidity in the banking market. Furthermore, we wonder whether elements such as setting a minimum reference capital or, even more, the uncertainty about how much this minimum will have to be, is acting as real minimum that prevents money from flowing. Despite the fact that litera-ture on bank regulatory practices is copious, analysts disagree as to whether the imposition of a minimum capital requirement actually reduces risk-taking incentives (Blum 1999). Chortareas et al. (2012, pp. 292-302) pro-vides an investigation of the impact of regulatory and supervisory approach-es on bank efficiency in the European Union (EU) during the period 2000-2008. They also point a number of studies (Rochet 1992, pp. 1137-1170; Gorton, Winton 1995; Hovakimian, Kane 2000, pp. 451-468), prior to crisis, which have emphasized the capital standards role in preventing bank failure. Holmstrom and Tirole (1998, pp. 1-40) focus on the lack of sufficient liquid-ity in the private sector as a rationale for government intervention. Rime (2001, pp. 789-805) claimed that the banks which find themselves close to the minimum regulatory capital requirement tend to increase their ratio of capital to risk-weighted assets.

Therefore, the aim of this paper is to contribute to the existing debate on the impact of stress test on banking system liquidity. Due to the theoretical character of the problem, the used methodology is a set of results from re-search and theoretical works. The remainder of our article is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the main stress tests done, and their main criti-cisms. Section 3 shows how banks may obtain liquidity and which trouble they could face in a crisis time; it reopens the old debate about whether regu-latory structures and styles of supervision should be adjusted, through ques-tion whether regulators and supervisors could react in other way than they

(4)

did; it also presents how a liquidity crisis may cause contagion by undermin-ing the confidence in other banks, because under uncertain conditions banks use the most pessimistic probability assessments. Finally, Section 4 offers some concluding remarks, limitations and further lines to work. After that, we show the references used in this paper.

Stress Tests

The Stress testing is an important risk management tool that is used to de-termine the stability of a given system or entity. This tool implies an evalua-tion beyond normal operaevalua-tional capacity, and an observaevalua-tion of its results. In the financial literature, the stress tests have traditionally referred only to an entity assets or portfolios, but more recently through the Basel II capital adequacy framework, have also been applied to the banks´ overall activity, as well as financial systems in general (BCBS 2009).

Furthermore, stress testing alerts bank management to adverse unex-pected outcomes related to a variety of risks and provides an indication of how much capital might be needed to absorb losses should large shocks oc-cur. As noted above, stress testing is a tool that supplements other risk man-agement approaches and measures. It plays a particularly important role in: providing forward-looking assessments of risk; overcoming limitations of models and historical data; supporting internal and external communication; feeding into capital and liquidity planning procedures; informing the setting of a banks’ risk tolerance; facilitating the development of risk mitigation or contingency plans across a range of stressed conditions. However, the finan-cial crisis has revealed a weakness in organizational aspects of stress testing programs, because at some banks it was performed mainly as an isolated exercise by the risk function with little interaction with other business areas. So, prior to crisis, most banks did not perform stress tests that took a com-prehensive firm wide perspective across risks. Even if they did, the stress tests were insufficient in identifying and aggregating risks. As a result, banks did not have a comprehensive view across credit, market and liquidity risks of their various businesses (BCBS 2009). In this way, during recent years we have attended the presentation and implementation of several stress tests both in the United States (US) and here in Europe. Table 1 shows the main characteristics of the four exercises and highlights the amount of information disclosed to investors.

While the United States stress tests and the first one carried out in Europe in 2010 only released a few key figures for each bank, the 2011 EU test was significantly more comprehensive, as it provided up to 3,400 data items for each bank; this included a breakdown of sovereign bonds and other credit

(5)

exposures by country and duration bands (Petrella, Resti 2012). Unfortunate-ly, in Europe there was a lot of criticism about the way in which test had been carried out and its outcomes (Saraiva, Biggadike 2010).

Table 1. Stress Test Exercises in de United States and European Union

E xe r ci se A n n ou n c e-n ou n c e-m e n t d at e R e su lt s d at e B an k s c o v -e r e d N . it e m s p e r b an k M in im u m c ap it a l ta r-ge t( s) C ap it al sh or tf a ll s fou n d 2009 Supervi-sory Capital Assessment Program (SCAP) by Federal Re-serve, FDIC, OCC, OTS Feb.10, 2009 May 7, 2009 19 domestic bank holding companies, covering 2/3 of the assets in the US banking system 17 Common Tier 1 at 4% Tier 1 at 6% 10 banks, USD 75 bn. 2010 EU Su-pervisory Capital Exer-cise by the Committee of European Banking Su-pervisors Dec.2, 2009 July 23, 2010 91 banks, covering 65% of the assets in the EU banking system and at least 50% for country 27 Tier 1 at 6% 7 banks (+17 “near fail”), €.3.5 bn. 2011 EU Stress Test by the European Banking Au-thority Jan.12, 2011 July 15, 2011 90 banks, covering 65% assets in the EU banking system and at least 50% for country 3,456 Core Tier 1 at 5% 8 banks (+16 “near fail”), €.2.5 bn. 2012 Compre-hensive Capital Analysis and Review (CCAR) by Federal Re-serve Nov.22, 2011 March 13, 2012 19 companies participating in the 2009 SCAP 41 Common Tier 1 at 5% lev-erage at 3-4% 4 (short-fall not disclosed)

(6)

Historical statistical relationships, such as correlations, proved to be unre-liable once actual events started to unfold. Even more, there were media suggestions that the authorities preferred a stronger stress test but were con-strained by political and banking pressures because bankers argued that giv-en the uncertainty in money markets, a disclosure of detailed information would exacerbate the crisis (Wilson 2011). Based on these contradictions, Cardinali and Nordmark (2011) studied the stock market reaction to the 2010 and 2011 EU stress tests by looking at for tested and untested banks. Their main findings were the following. First, the 2010 results were relatively un-informative to investors. Secondly, the announcement of the methodology to be used in 2011 triggered negative cumulative abnormal returns for stress-tested banks, while non-stress-tested institutions were roughly unaffected. Then, it is possible to question why stress tests did not show properly the real risk on investments that was trying to set. A potential answer would be that the choice and construction of stress tests must apply criteria of reasonableness.

But these criteria are necessarily subjective, since the risks to consider are generally relied on historical precedent and not on a virtually endless host of improbable reasons (Abbink 2011, pp. 421-434).

Facing criticism about the rigour of the tests (The Financial Times 2011; Finch et al. 2011; Burke 2011), the European Banking Authority (EBA) (2011) pointed to the huge financial information disclosed in the last trial done (91 banks and more than 3,200 data points per each). However these data were filled with anomalies, mainly relating to aggregation of data and omissions. Thus, there were risks that were not covered in sufficient detail in those stress tests. For example, in sovereign bonds held in the banks’ books a credit rating downgrade of the issuer was specified in the test. For Greek bonds, this translated into a stress scenario of 15% loss, which was below their market prices (21%). Similar problems existed with the Irish and Por-tuguese bonds, where market prices implied losses around 30-40%; and for Spanish and Italian bonds, where the losses were below the levels seen in trading. So the test results significantly underestimated the losses if Greece, Ireland and Portugal were default and the Spain and Italy experienced a seri-ous financial pressure as they did.

Other stress elements were also insufficiently tested. The modest drop in growth and rise in unemployment contrasted with the sharp contraction in economic activity and employment seen in the peripheral European econo-mies. Given the stated desire of the EU to bring public finances and budget deficits in line with guidelines, the risk of a long period of stagnation (low growth and high unemployment) and its effect on loan losses could not be discounted. The assumption of a 15% fall in stock prices could understate the potential volatility. The 10-17% fall in property prices looked benign due to, for example, Spanish property prices, which were still highly valuated.

(7)

This overvaluation was exacerbated by unwillingness on the part of lenders to take possession of and sell assets securing loans, which would bring losses (Das 2011).

Furthermore, by a quirk of fate during the 2011´s test, Helaba German bank was withdrawn to avoid public failure (BBC 2011). Another good ex-ample of how wrong stress testing was could be seen in Allied Irish Banks Plc and Bank of Ireland Plc, which passed the EU’s examinations in 2010, while Anglo Irish Bank Corp. wasn’t tested. Later that year, a liquidity short-fall prompts EU governments and the International Monetary Fund to agree on an 85 billion euro bailout for the country.

In the same way, Dexiagot a clean bill of health in 2011 EU´s stress tests and less than three months after that, France and Belgium considered a se-cond bailout. Here, the answer seems obvious. Dexia was able to exclude the paper losses on its sovereign bonds to calculate its capital ratios in that test. Meanwhile, Bankia problem was that its core (Caja Madrid, Bancaja) was drowned by the crisis because the real estate bubble explosion caught squarely.

Bankia has been observed in international markets as the extreme case of a general situation in the Spanish financial system, highly burdened by the exposure to the real estate sector because of reckless loans and investments held for years.

As a consequence, cases such as the Irish banking system, Dexia or Bankia have brought about the accumulation of inaccuracies in the stress tests, as well as influences or pressures suspicion have created a crisis of confidence, hard to restore without sufficient honesty signs from supervisory authorities. Nowadays, the financial sector, affected by that lack of confi-dence is unable to perform its natural function: to provide credit to the econ-omy.

Liquidity Crisis

Liquidity is a core concept inside current economic problems, which is commonly defined as the ratio between loans and deposits. It shows how much a bank has used its lending capacity. However, this ratio, without fur-ther data, could hide doubtful quality assets because, as it is defined, all loans are short-term and self-liquidating. Then, a comprehensive study of bank liquidity should include several ratios, one for each maturity category. Therefore, if banks´ debts mature before their credit does, they will not ful-fill its obligations unless they obtain money. Hence, it is possible to have a solvent heritage, being in an illiquidity status or economic bankruptcy, since it is also necessary the conversion in cash of the values of its assets

(8)

(including receivables). This means that banks are forced to sell their long-term loans to the Central Bank to ‘raise cash’ and meet its short-long-term debts. Another way for firms to generate liquidity is to sell assets. However, the level of liquidity can affect the value of these assets. Yet banks, once they start this process, are launching a vicious circle, in which falling liquidity reduces asset values, which, in turn, leads to lower liquidity, and so on (Elul 2008, pp. 13-22).

The illiquidity also imposes challenges to risk measurement from lack of correlation data for assets that do not mark frequently to market, that is as-sets such as real estate or private equity, which are illiquid by nature. So it is implausible that quantitative methods for ascribing an estimated volatility to assets can carry much conviction. It is even more so, when they are applied to assets that seldom mark-to-market at all, particularly when pricing mech-anisms has become distorted (Abbink 2011, pp. 421-434).

Aikman et al. (2009) demonstrate how rising funding costs and liquidity concerns can amplify other sources of risk. Thus, in the Van den End´s (2010) liquidity stress-tester model, the second round feedback effects are determined by the number and size of reacting banks and the similarity of reactions. Contagion results from the effects of balance sheet adjustments on prices and volumes in the markets and funding channels where banks are exposed (Van den End 2011).

In conclusion, financial intermediaries serve to provide firms’ and inves-tors’ liquidity needs, but during liquidity crises they fail to function properly. It is so because they accumulate liquidity as a way to avoid selling in the interbank market at fire sale prices. This reaction may cause contagion in cascades by undermining confidence in other banks, as Aikman et al. (2009) set.

Regulatory Crisis

‘Is the theory underlying our banking legislation wrong, or have our banks constantly been in a perilous condition, and is it because of investment loan-ing that we have had recurrloan-ing financial disasters?’ This Moulton´s ques-tion (1918c, pp. 705-731) was asked nearly a century ago and still remains valid. Thereby, from early 1990’s onwards there has been a debate, both from academic and policy circles, about the ways in which regulatory struc-tures and styles of supervision should be adjusted to face more complex fi-nancial institutions, more complicated fifi-nancial products, and highly adap-tive markets which tended to find ways around any given set of rules (Regling, Watson 2010). In this sense, Chortareas et al. (2012, pp. 292-302) allude to how regulation may interfere with the efficient operation of banks.

(9)

Thus, whenever regulation is implemented with the aim of restricting or limiting banks’ activities, their business conduct and efficiency with which they operate are affected. This is because banks may react to a higher regula-tory burden by engaging in more risky activities and invest in ways that cir-cumvent regulation.

Hence, some authors had warned that the architecture for resolving prob-lems within the European single financial market has been deficient. There was concern about the ability to manage liquidity or solvency difficulties. On the liquidity side, the worry focused on the absence of clear guidelines for implementing the EU lender of last resort function in situations when banks would experience problems. On the solvency side, the cares were the lack of clear arrangements and the resolution of cross-border banking crises (Pisani-Ferry, Sapir 2010, pp. 341-372). This debate was not conclusive and some countries decided to set up a separate unified financial regulator, while others preferred formulas that left banking supervision in the hands of the central bank. Thereupon, some countries shifted towards ‘principles-based’ regulation which deemphasized specific rules that could be side-stepped; as well as some countries adopted even ‘less intrusive’ approaches, sometimes described as ‘light touch’ supervision. Then, to say that the EU was institu-tionally ill-prepared to manage a financial crisis, especially one involving systemic cross-border institutions, would certainly not be an overstatement. Even more, focused on risk analysis terms, regulators and supervisors were not entirely blind to the build-up of possible vulnerabilities. They were aware of risks in exposure to the property sector, if prices should fall steeply. But four key elements, among others, typically combined to dissuade them from taking forceful action to restrain the banks (Regling, Watson 2010): 1. They did not consider it their job to react to the macroeconomic

compo-nent of the problems that were potentially building up. There was in any case no strong consensus among economists how much of the fall in global interest rates, the decline in risk premia, or the rise in local asset prices should be viewed as unsustainable.

2. Liquidity supervision (as opposed to solvency) had been off the core Ba-sel agenda for decades; and few regulators performed stress tests that combined asset market with funding shocks. In the euro area, financial in-tegration and interdependency were goals of policy, and the side-effects on vulnerability were not strongly emphasized.

3. It was unclear to many supervisors what instruments to use to counter macrofinancial risks. A few acted to limit loan-to-value ratios; increased reserve requirements, or imposed heavier provisioning as risks built up. But in a setting of strong cross-border competition, there was also a con-cern that such actions might just penalize locally owned banks.

(10)

4. Thus, many supervisors – faced with complex assets and operations, and with banks’ ability to work around specific rules – moved to rely more on banks’ own risk assessment systems and to supervise processes and prin-ciples, with some moving very far in the direction not just of ‘principles-based’ but of ‘light-touch’ supervision.

Finally, in order to understand why and what has been happening, it is necessary to realize that the banks have been historically protected by states against their creditors, basing on the principles of ‘too many to fail’ (Achar-ya, Yorulmazer 2007, pp. 1-31) and ‘too big to fail’ 1 (Freixas 1999; Goodhart, Huang 2000).

Under these two doctrines a bank can continue to operate if the State con-siders it, being outside the bankruptcy law applicable to any person or com-pany. This banks´ protection has helped them to ignore the basic principles of safety and liquidity, and has led to a mismatch between the maturities of balance´s assets and liabilities. In fact, there were some banks and other fi-nancial institutions which engaged in lending practices that were dangerous in an ‘old banking’ way. These practices did not require special supervisory imagination or moral courage to penalize. The failure of supervisors to act strongly against such practices is much harder to understand (Regling, Wat-son 2010).

Thereupon, all these capital adequacy rules might specify how much capital each bank should hold, but if such rules do not truly reflect the risks involved they could unintentionally induce banks to hold either too much or not enough capital. Insufficient capital increases the danger of bank failure while excessive capital imposes unnecessary costs on banks and their cus-tomers with adverse implications for the efficiency of the banking system (Chortareas et al. 2012, pp. 292-302).

Confidence Crisis

During any liquidity crises banks experience an investor confidence loss, making it difficult to raise further cash. If a bank has insufficient cash re-serves, it could run into a vicious circle, where the bank cannot pay its debts

1

The Financial Stability Board (2011) released a list of 29 banks worldwide that they considered as "systemically important financial institutions". Of the list, 17 are based in Eu-rope, 8 in the U.S., and 4 in Asia: Bank of America, Bank of China, Bank of New York Mellon, Banque Populaire CdE, Barclays, BNP Paribas, Citigroup, Commerzbank, Credit Suisse, Deutsche Bank, Dexia, Goldman Sachs, Group Crédit Agricole, HSBC, ING Bank, JPMorgan Chase, Lloyds Banking Group, Mitsubishi UFJ FG, Mizuho FG, Morgan Stanley, Nordea, Royal Bank of Scotland, Santander, Société Générale, State Street, Sumitomo Mitsui FG, UBS, Unicredit Group, Wells Fargo.

(11)

because it has no funds, but cannot raise funds as its financial difficulties result in the downgrading of its debt. Furthermore, the actual vicious spiral between sovereign debt and banking crises has been compounded by the decision, first taken in Ireland and later followed in Spain’s Bankia crisis, to shift the burden of rescues onto the public budget. Fears of a repeat of the post-Lehman disaster have been one reason; another has been pressure by creditor countries to spare their banks from any losses on their exposure (Micossi 2012). In this way, in Caballero and Krishnamurthy’s model (2008, pp. 2195-2230), a sudden liquidity shock hits some firms in the economy and generates a need for borrowing. But those firms which had not been affected by this first shock grow concerned that they may be hit by the se-cond shock, even though the sese-cond shock is very unlikely. The unaffected firms react by preemptively drawing down their own lines of credit. That is, they hoard liquidity. The result is that there is much less available for those firms that actually need liquidity because they have been hit by the first shock. Thus, they assume that market participants are uncertainty averse. In this sense, Ellsberg’s paradox (1961, pp. 643-669) demonstrated that ambi-guity influences decisions in a way that is incompatible with standard ver-sions of rationality. Greater ambiguity could imply greater variability in outcomes, but variability can have a downside. So, a prudent agent could regard ambiguity as a tell-tale marker of high variability and decide accord-ingly. That is, when evaluating outcomes about which they are uncertain, they use the most pessimistic probability assessments. In particular, each participant overweights the probability that he will be among those hit by the second shock. This creates a desire to hoard liquidity against this unlikely shock.

For those reasons, half a decade after what is considered to have been the start of the credit crunch, the public are more disappointed with the banking sector than ever, as well as with regulators and supervisors who were unable to monitor the proper functioning of the banks in order to avoid the two re-cessions suffered by the economy since the beginning.

Conclusions

The depth and duration of the financial crisis has led many banks and super-visory authorities, as well as academic and media to question whether stress testing practices were sufficient, prior and after crisis. Also, it led us to ques-tion whether those tools were adequate to cope with rapidly changing cir-cumstances. In particular, not only was the crisis far more severe in many respects than it was indicated by banks' stress testing results (BCBS 2009), but it was possibly compounded by an unwanted feedback effect, because of

(12)

weaknesses in stress testing practices resulting from reaction to the unfolded events. Nonetheless, stress tests convey information to the market that goes beyond the disclosure of more detailed data (Petrella, Resti 2012), and crisis has revealed serious flaws with relying solely on such an approach to restore confidence to the markets. Indeed, the effect was the opposite completely. At the most fundamental level, the tests assumed that risk is driven by a known and constant statistical process. Firstly, because given a long period of stabil-ity backward-looking historical information indicated benign conditions, so that these models did not pick up the possibility of severe shocks, nor the build up of vulnerabilities within the system. Secondly, the financial crisis has again shown that, especially in stressed conditions, risk characteristics can change rapidly as reactions by market participants within the system can induce feedback effects and lead to system-wide interactions. These effects could dramatically amplify initial shocks, as recent crisis have illustrated. Finally, extreme reactions occur rarely and might carry little weight in mod-els that rely on historical data. It also means that they are hard to model quantitatively (BCBS 2009). For these reasons, banks underestimated the strong interlinkages between the lack of market liquidity and funding liquidi-ty pressures which led to a lack of confidence in the main tool to restore the cited trust lost.

On the other hand, with the benefit of hindsight, a widely accepted lesson of the crisis is that ‘intrusiveness’ into banks’ risk management and govern-ance had been set aside too lightly. A closer and intrusive supervision, unlike ‘light touch’ regulation, could identify problems earlier and in some cases prevent or mitigate their effects (Regling, Watson 2010). So, experience has shown that changes of approach among supervisors allowed a build-up of vulnerabilities, even without the shock to liquidity that followed the Lehman Brothers failure; as the ongoing credit crisis has illustrated how increased funding costs and the closure of funding markets can trigger bank failure (Aikman et al. 2009). Likewise, as noted above, capital and liquidity stand-ards affect bank lending behaviour and thereby the economy.

In conclusion, the stress-testing use as tool to recover the lost confidence in banking system as well as their supervisors could be questionable. Conse-quently, until the actual uncertainty does not become in risk again, through the confidence recovery cited, economic agents would consider the most unfavourable option as the most probable one, which would lead them to hoard liquidity, which prevents a proper capital flow.

Nonetheless, our investigations into this area are still ongoing and the present study is the first step towards enhancing our understanding of rela-tionship between stress testing and liquidity crises linked to confidence cri-ses and regulation cricri-ses. A further investigation seems desirable to avoid or mitigate a future similar situation.

(13)

References

Abbink J.B. (2011), Constructing stress tests, “Journal of Risk Finance”, Vol. 12, Issue 5.

Acharya V., Yorulmazer T. (2007), Too Many to Fail – An Analysis of

Time-Inconsistency in Bank Closure Policies, “Journal of Financial Intermediation”,

Vol. 16, Issue 1.

Aikman D., Alessandri P., Eklund B., Gai P., Kapadia S., Martin E., Mora N., Sterne G., Willison M. (2009), Funding liquidity risk in a quantitative model of

system-ic stability, June, Bank of England, Working Paper, No. 372.

BBC (2011), German bank Helaba to pull out of stress tests, 13 July, BBC News Business.

BCBS, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (2009), Principles for sound stress

testing practices and supervision, May, Bank for International Settlements.

Blum J. (1999), Do bank capital adequacy requirements reduce risks in banking?, “Journal of Banking and Finance”, Vol. 23.

Brunetti C., Di Filippo M., Harris J.H. (2011), Effects of Central Bank Intervention

on the Interbank Market during the Subprime Crisis, “Review of Financial

Stud-ies”, Vol. 24, Issue 6.

Burke M. (2011), The support given to EU banks is killing the recovery, 17 July, The Guardian.

Caballero R.J., Krishnamurthy A. (2008), Collective Risk Management in a Flight to

Quality Episode, “Journal of Finance”, Vol. LXIII, No. 5.

Cardinali A., Nordmark J. (2011), How informative are Bank Stress Tests?: Bank

Opacity in the European Union, Master Thesis in Finance, Lund University.

Chortareas G., Girardone C., Ventouri A. (2012) Bank supervision, regulation, and

efficiency: Evidence from the European Union, “Journal of Financial Stability”,

Vol. 8, Issue 4.

Das S. (2011), The EBA Stress Tests – Not the Real Thing, 26 July, Eurointelligence, Dash E. (2009), If Its Too Big to Fail, Is It Too Big to Exist?, “New York Times”,

Week in Review, 20 June,

Ellsberg D. (1961), Risk, Ambiguity, and the Savage Axioms, “Quarterly Journal of Economics”, Vol. 75, No. 4.

Elul R. (2008), Liquidity Crises, “Business Review”, Q2.

European Banking Authority (EBA) (2011), Eu-Wide Stress Test Aggregate Report, 15 July.

Financial Stability Board (2011), Policy Measures to Address Systemically

Im-portant Financial Institutions, 04 November.

Finch G., Martinuzzi E., Penty C. (2011), EU Bank Stress Tests Missing Sovereign

Defaults Fail to Convince Analysts, 18 July, Bloomberg.

Freixas X. (1999), Optimal bailout policy, conditionality and constructive

ambigui-ty, 15 December, Financial Market Group Discussion Paper 237, London School

of Economics.

Goodhart C., Huang H. (2000), A Simple Model of an International Lender of Last

Resort, “Economic Notes”, Vol. 29, Issue 1.

Gorton, G. and Winton, A. (1995). Bank capital regulation in general equilibrium. Wharton Financial Institutions Centre, Working Paper.

(14)

Holmstrom B., Tirole J. (1998), Private and Public Supply of Liquidity, “Journal of Political Economy”, Vol. 106, No 1.

Hovakimian A., Kane E.J. (2000), Effectiveness of capital regulation at U.S.

com-mercial banks, 1985 to 1994. “ Journal of Finance” Vol. 55.

Micossi S. (2012), Unholy compromise in the eurozone and how to right it, July, CEPS, No. 277.

Moulton H.G. (1918a), Commercial Banking and Capital Formation: I, “Journal of Political Economy”, Vol. 26, No. 5.

Moulton H.G. (1918b), Commercial Banking and Capital Formation: II, “Journal of Political Economy”, Vol. 26, No. 6.

Moulton H.G. (1918c), Commercial Banking and Capital Formation: III, “Journal of Political Economy”, Vol. 26, No. 7.

Petrella G., Resti A. (2012), Supervisors as Information Producers: Do Stress Tests

Reduce Bank Opaqueness?, June, 2nd International Conference of the Financial

Engineering and Banking Society (F.E.B.S): Recent Developments in Financial Markets and Banking, London.

Pisani-Ferry, J., Sapir A. (2010), Banking crisis management in the EU: an early

assessment, “Economic Policy”, Issue 62.

Regling K., Watson M. (2010), A Preliminary Report on The Sources of Irelands

Banking Crisis, May, Preliminary Report, Commission of Investigation into the

Banking Sector in Ireland.

Rime B. (2001), Capital Requirements and Bank Behaviour: Empirical Evidence for

Switzerland, “Journal of Banking and Finance”, Vol. 25, Issue 4.

Rochet J. (1992), Capital requirements and the behavior of commercial banks, “Eu-ropean Economic Review”, Vol. 36, Issue 5.

Saraiva C., Biggadike O. (2010), Euro Falls as Stress Test Results Fail to Alleviate

Banking Risk Concern, 24 July.

Summers B. (1975), Loan commitments to business in United States banking history, “Economic Review”, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond.

The Financial Times (2011), Not that stressful, 17 July, The Financial Times. Van den End J.W. (2010), Liquidity Stress-Tester: A Model for Stress-testing Banks

Liquidity Risk, CESifo Economic Studies, Vol. 56, Issue 1.

Van den End W.A. (2011), Credit and liquidity risk of banks in stress conditions:

Analyses from a macro perspective, October, Ph.D. Thesis, University of

Gro-ningen.

Wilson H. (2011), European Banking Authority was hobbled over stress tests, 17 July, The Telegraph.

Cytaty

Powiązane dokumenty

Wraz z powstaniem domu formacyjnego w Swobnicy wiele się zmieniło. Na potrzeby nowicjatu zaadaptowano i przebudowano do celów mieszkalnych po- mieszczenia dawnej stodoły

The gross minimum wage at the time amounted to 1,317 PLN and the net wage amounted to 948.15 PLN, with the total cost of labour incurred by an employer amounting to 1,560.39 PLN,

Istotnym impulsem współczesnych przeobraz˙en´ polskiej polityki społecznej miało sie˛ stac´ członkostwo w Unii Europejskiej i koniecznos´c´ dostosowania niektórych rozwi ˛

In the food industry, much greater importance than the fluid whey, have whey-derived formulations such as whey powder, demineralised whey powder, whey protein concentrates

bardziej rozumienie narodowej historii państwa było oparte na zasadach myślenia naukowego, tym mocniejszy stawał się konflikt między historią a polityką. Naukowe poznanie

Ustawa o utrzymaniu czystości, w zakresie, w jakim wy- znacza sferę obowiązków właścicieli nieruchomości, należy do.. Wynika stąd obowiązek dokonywania ścisłej wykładni

The paper deals with the problem of takitng represen'tative samples 1n the case when any fealtUJre of. a given series arud~ed changes contoinuo~ly. UlIlder such

Wśród istotnych przyczyn kryzysu wy- mienia się nadmierną ekspansję instytucji finansowych na rynku kredytów subpri- me udzielanych osobom bez zdolności kredytowej, i