• Nie Znaleziono Wyników

The Impact of Technological and Structural Changes in the National Economy on the Labour-Capital Relations

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "The Impact of Technological and Structural Changes in the National Economy on the Labour-Capital Relations"

Copied!
10
0
0

Pełen tekst

(1)

The aim of the research presented in this paper is to show the relations between labour and capital in the national economy, resulting from technological and structural changes taking place in the years 1991 to 2008 and to indicate of their importance for economic growth.

The paper presents the functional determinants for the Polish economy in 1991-2008 affecting the phenomenon subject to study as well as the preliminary analysis of relations between capital and labour and their impact on the GDP. In the research the econometric methods of description and inference based on the concept of macroeconomic Cobb-Douglas production function in both static and dynamic approach were used. The study shows that increase in production in the na- tional economy was largely the result of capital growth during the analysed period. The main factor of economic growth however in the years 1998 to 2008 was the technological progress. The results may be the implication for economic policy in terms of investment and employment.

Introduction

The transformation of the Polish economy has con- tributed to the elimination of a number of distortions functioning on the labour market. Dynamic structural changes forming the basis for a new economic system – privatization and restructuring of enterprises in the initial transition period – led to both negative and positive changes on this market. From the standpoint of the labour market, the negative effects of impact of the implemented reforms include, inter alia, the loss of jobs and rising unemployment as well as decreased

professional activity of the population. The positive effect of the changes include the process of rationali- sation of the labour resources consisting in the adap- tation of the structure of involved resources and meth- ods of their use to the existing economic conditions.

Companies began to pay increasing attention to labour productivity. Available technical devices generated by the involved capital required adapting the labour re- sources to a level resulting from the economic calcu- lation. The labour rationalization process is continu- ous and characteristic of any market economy. Only its causes change. One of them is striving to achieve a competitive advantage of companies and their fur- ther development. It should be emphasized that the increasing international mobility of production factors

The Impact of Technological and Structural Changes in the National

Economy on the Labour-Capital Relations

Received: 18112011 Accepted: 1603 2012

ABSTRACT

D40, O40 KEy woRdS:

JEL Classification:

transformation, structural changes, employment, capital, national economy, macroeconomic production function

1 Gdańsk University of Technology, POLAND

2 Sopot College, POLAND

Corespondence concerning to this article should be addressed to:

mgaw@zie.pg.gda.pl

Małgorzata Gawrycka, Aneta Sobiechowska-Ziegert1, Anna Szymczak2

(2)

creates the need for flexible adjustment of resources to current market needs, which ensures maintaining competitive position on an international scale.

By making structural changes individual countries aim to reduce development disparities compared to highly developed countries. The result of the ongoing changes is the observed convergence processes. Stud- ies by Caselli and Tenreyro (2005), Ben-David (1993) and Berman, Bound and Machin (1998) show that in the years 1950-2000 there occurred real convergence associated with offsetting the level of GDP per capita and labour productivity. Real convergence in GDP per capita concerned cutting down the span of GDP per capita among others in Greece compared with France and the EU countries in relation to the U.S.

In order to deepen the analysis of structural changes taking place in the Polish economy, it seems relevant to identify the causes of real convergence. The literature on the subject refers to four types of convergence (Ca- selli & Tenreyro, 2005):

• neoclassical, which is based on the assumption that countries with a lower stock of capital grow faster, because it is possible to increase the return on the capital employed,

• related to overcoming technological backwardness (explained by the theories of endogenous growth) – convergence is due to the flow of modern tech- nological solutions from countries with high levels of new technologies to countries with a low level of technological development,

• associated with international trade, which is ex- plained by the creation of bigger exchange oppor- tunities on a common market for countries inte- grating with those that have so far remained within the structures of a given market,

• structural transformation which resulting from the reallocation of production factors between sectors of the economy (movement from sectors with low productivity of labour and capital to sectors with higher productivity).

Each of those types of convergence has an effect on changes on the labour market. It is difficult to clearly identify which one of them most significantly affected the degree of utilization of labour resources, because in 1991-2008 several processes took place simultane- ously: transformation, restructuring, integration and globalization. Literature suggests that the intensity of

structural changes in the national economy is high in the period of accelerated technological and organi- zational progress, quick economic growth, modern- ization of the economy, structural changes and those resulting from changes in foreign trade. All of the processes were characteristic of the Polish economy in the aforementioned years and contributed to its development and a significant reduction in the gap between the Polish economy and the world's leading economies. In terms of economic development mea- sured by GDP per capita, Poland is still at a very distant position, even in comparison with the least developed countries of Western Europe.

In the endogenous growth models the difference in the levels of development of economies is explained not only by the accumulation of physical capital but also by the accumulation of human capital. Human capital has become a production factor expressing a certain level of technical expertise. The inclusion of technical knowl- edge growths to the production function as a produc- tion factor causes that the level of growth adjusted by the level of technological development depends on the accumulation of physical capital, i.e. investments and savings. It should be noted, however, that the growth rate of investment in physical capital, and therefore the savings for those investments, depends on the growth of human capital resource designed to “support” the new stock of physical capital (Pońsko, 2000).

One may find that by increasing the effectiveness of the particular production factors technological prog- ress will contribute to the growth of competitiveness of a given country. In order to determine the impact of technological progress on the production capacity of the economy, in further considerations of this study only the impact of two production factors was exam- ined: labour (L) and capital (C) and their impact on the GDP.

Rarely does technological progress affect capital and labour efficiency in a balanced way (neutral technolog- ical progress). It usually changes their relation in the production process by increasing labour productivity (labour-multiplying technological progress) or capital productivity (capital-multiplying technological prog- ress). In the long run technological progress produces two opposite effects: the effect of capitalization and re- duction of jobs. The effect of capitalization, in the case of neutral technological progress, contributes to the

(3)

increased demand for labour. Whereas, capital-based technological progress reduces it. Thanks to the pro- cess of reallocation of labour resources across sectors of the national economy, technological progress does not necessarily have to lead to changes in the employ- ment level in the long run (Bukowski & Dyrda, 2009).

The aim of the research presented in this paper is to present the relationship between labour and capital in the national economy resulting from technological as well as structural changes taking place in the years from 1991 to 2008 and indication of their importance for economic growth.

Technological changes taking place in the economy depend on the achieved economic growth and the level of ongoing investment. Both processes are de- termined by changes in the external environment and institutional reforms on the labour market. The effects of structural reforms for the labour market with em- phasis on technological changes are presented on the figure 1. The number of jobs offered in the economy is influenced by labour demand and labour supply, to- gether with its specific features. The demand for labour depends on the activity of the economy (economic

growth) and technological changes that determine the intensity of the use of work and qualification require- ments. Labour supply is determined primarily by two factors: the number of working-age population and the degree of the population’s professional activity. The first of those factors is exogenous, because changes in the number of working-age population are largely de- termined by the birth rate from before at least 18 years.

In the case of the second factor, the most significant seem to be the wages and the unemployment benefits, as well as legislation influencing the labour market.

Tangible investments are the main determinant of technological changes implemented in an enterprise.

By increasing the amount of capital they contribute to the increase in the production capacity of the enter- prise in the future. We must remember that a manu- facturing process consumes physical capital. In order to maintain the existing capital stock it is necessary to reconstruct it. In the available sources the measure of capital accounting for both investment processes, as well as the amortisation of assets (depreciation) is the net value of fixed assets.

THE IMPACT OF T&S CHANGES IN THE NATIONAL ECONOMY 17

employment in countries at different stages of development.] Warszawa: PWE.

Zienkowski, L. (2002). Efekty transformacji i perspektywy rozwoju gospodarki polskiej. [Effects of transformation and development prospects of the Polish economy]. In A.

Welfe (Ed), Modele i polityka makroekonomiczna [Macroeconomic Models and Policy]

(165-189). Warszawa: PWE.

Figure 1. Impact of structural and technological changes on employment in national economy

Source: Own study based on (Weller, 2001).

Figure 2.The rate of change of GDP, the net values of fixed assets and employment in 1998-2008

long term trends in labour markets

changes in external environment, international division of labour, labour mobility

institutional reforms of the labour market

institutions, markets, production factors, business entities

labour market and labour market institutions

economic growth

investment rate

technological changes

employment in the economy employment in economy sectors

labour supply, demographic trends, professional activity, education and continuous learning

income distribution

Figure 1. Impact of structural and technological changes on employment in national economy

Note. Adapted from Weller, J. (2001). Economic reforms, growth and employment: Labor markets in Latin America and Caribbean. Chile: ECLAC.

(4)

An enterprise, guided by economic calculation aims at such a combination of production factors which will contribute to achieving the desired effects, such as an increase in goodwill. As a consequence of those processes specific relationships between the amount of involved physical capital and work will emerge. The structure of capital and labour depends on the relationship between their prices and the effi- ciency of use of individual resources. Therefore, capi- tal can be both complementary for and substitutive with labour. For a complementary relation, a manu- facturing process can not occur in the absence of even one of the production factors. Thus, capital growth generates increased employment. However, the sub- stitution effect influences the employment drop as a result of replacing one factor with another, in this case – labour with capital.

The empirical research conducted by Ripatti and Vilmunen (2001) for the economy of Finland shows that clear complementarity (low substitution rate) occurred between capital and labour. This example appears to be particularly interesting because of the strong technological changes and structural adjust- ments that occurred in that country after 1990. The authors of the study explain the low substitutability level between capital and labour with the nature of technological progress dominant in Finland. There occurred the so-called Schumpeter process of de- struction of jobs with low productivity level (Ripatti

& Vilmunen, 2001; Wojtyna, 2010). They concluded that the low elasticity of substitution of labour and capital does not result from the specific structure of economic institutions in a given country (e.g. USA and Finland), but rather reflects the aspects of tech- nology and production (Jalava, Pohjola, Ripatti &

Vilmunen, 2006).

Research Methodology

In order to achieve the defined empirical objective econometric methods of description and inference were used. These methods help review the operation of overall economic rules in relation to specific com- munities.

The most commonly used methods to describe the relation between capital and labour on the one hand and product on the other are two functions: CES and Cobb-Douglas. There has been a discussion going on

in the literature for years on the advisability of using these functions (Mulat, 1980). Both have advantages and disadvantages. The CES function occurs in many variants allowing to conduct research using spatial or time series data, and allows the estimation of elastici- ty of substitution of production factors. In its original form it is criticized as overly restrictive because of the assumption of no impact of technological progress on the marginal productivity of production factors.

The Cobb-Douglas function is simple in terms of es- timating the parameters that determine production flexibility against the changes of labour and capital (Tokarski, 2003), but it is criticized for being gener- ally easily adaptable to empirical data, even if it does not provide a satisfactory economic interpretation (Miller, 2008; Aiyar & Dalgaard, 2009). Initial esti- mates made by the authors during the study period show that the elasticity of substitution of production factors is close to one. Therefore, the authors decided to use the Cobb-Douglas production function. The Cobb-Douglas production function in its general form can be presented as follows:

Y e =

α0

× C

α1

× L

α2 [1]

where: Y – production volume, C – capital expendi- tures, L – workload, α - parameter projecting produc- tion growth if the workload increases by one.

It results from the characteristic of the power func- tion that the flexibility of the Cobb-Douglas function against (C) and (L) is constant and equal respectively:

E dy dC

C

y C/

= ⋅ = – y

1 [2]

E dy dL

L

y L/

= ⋅ = – y

2 [3]

Therefore, if – ceteris paribus – the amount of capi- tal increases by 1%, the production volume increases by α1%, and with the increase in workload by 1% the production volume increases by α2% (subject to capital stability). The Cobb-Douglas function also allows the interpretation of the simultaneous impact of changes of the factors on the production, that is the flexibility of

(5)

production against the scale of outlays. This elasticity is equal to the degree of homogeneity of function1:

E d y = + d y

y/λ

λ

λ λ

= × λ α α

1 2 [4]

Thus, if all production factors simultaneously increase by 1%, the production volume will increase by (α1 + α2)%

In order to measure the impact of technological change on the production value, it is necessary to choose the form of aggregate production function, which is associated with the adoption of certain as- sumptions on the structure of relations between the production factors and the impact of technological progress on them. For statistical data presented in the form of time series a dynamic Cobb-Douglas is often used which takes the following form:

1 2

Y e C L e e

t

=

α0

α α

⋅ ⋅

α 3t

εt [5]

The time variable t represents the so-called technical progress factor which means that the same level of la- bour and capital outlays leads to an increase in pro- duction. Therefore, we can say that in every period the value of production increases eα3 times, i.e. the relative increase in the production value is eα3– 1.

The initial task in the construction of an economet- ric model is to define the independent variables. The selection criterion should be the substantive knowl- edge of the studied phenomenon. One should choose such factors (independent variables) that have a signif- icant influence on the phenomenon studied (depend- ent variable). In this article, the production measure Y is the GDP at current prices, the value of labour L is the average employment in national economy and the capital C is the value of net assets.

Adopting the net value of fixed assets as a measure of capital can be debatable. The authors realise that the depreciated fixed assets may still be used in produc- tion processes and thus increase the GDP. In the Cobb- Douglas model, the capital may be the gross value of fixed assets (Tokarski, 2010). However, it appears that the measure of capital proposed in this paper – the net value of fixed assets – is consistent with the economic theory. The future capital resources may vary from the

accumulated capital resources C1 in two ways. First, new capital can be invested (I). Secondly, amortisation may partially reduce the value of the capital resources.

The new capital value will then amount to C2 = C1 + I – δC1. Where: C2 is the new capital resources, C1 – former capital, I – gross investments, δC1 – amortisation. C2 corresponds to the net value of fixed assets. In order for the capital resources (C2) to grow, new investments must exceed amortisation (Burda & Wyplosz, 2000).

That measure of capital also provides greater diagnos- tic capabilities. By indicating the extent to which gross GDP depends on the value of this indicator, it draws the attention to the reconstruction and modernization processes increasing the efficiency of capital.

Research results

In the first years of transformation of Polish economy (1990-1994) a decline in production, measured in constant prices, could be observed. In the subject lit- erature Lipowski and Winiecki point that the cause of this phenomenon was the structural deformation of the economy of real socialism, which was character- ized by waste of resources, by both the consumer and producer (as cited in Bałtowski & Miszewski, 2007, p. 200). The “market-redundant” industrial produc- tion representing an immanent feature of the centrally planned economy included, according to the classifica- tion of Lipowski (as cited in Bałtowski & Miszewski, 2007, p. 200), three separate groups of production: un- wanted production, irrational production and politi- cal production. An example of unwanted production may be excess storage of stocks accumulated by firms and households during the economy of shortages. The second group is the production of end-user goods at low prices (with high subsidies) used for consumption or further processing, frequently wasted. Political pro- duction means manufacturing of intermediate goods used for the realisation of investments provided for in the central plan undertaken without carrying out the investment efficiency calculation and military produc- tion produced in excess and at inflated costs.

Economic system reform began in 1989, amending the existing economic order, eliminated the features of the previous system, while contributing to a decline in

1 The function is homogenous at the degree θ > 0 if

∀ > λ 0 f x ( ) λ = f x ( λ

2

,..., λ x

k

) = λ

θ

f x ( )

(6)

production. A substantial part of economic potential of state-owned enterprises was destroyed and many areas of domestic production collapsed due to the lack of demand and the opening of the economy. Accord- ing to a study by Lipowski, Glikman and Winiecki, the fall in production in the first years of transition was for the most part nothing more than getting rid of the structural deformation and the wastage of resources during the time of real socialism (as cited in Bałtowski

& Miszewski, 2007, p.206).

In the centrally planned economy, the labour mar- ket also functioned improperly. Guaranteed employ- ment characteristic of the past regime (the so-called full employment) led to huge excess of employment, which is unemployment in the workplace. Recession and new rules of economic behaviour, as a result of the stabilization program, revealed unemployment. It must be emphasized that transformation changes in Poland coincided with the global industrial and in- formation revolution by which the labour-consuming technologies were (and still are) replaced with labour- saving ones, which in turn contributed even more to the reduction of employment.

In subsequent years, i.e. after 1994, restructuring processes resulting from changes in the economic sys- tem were still under way. Therefore, when conducting the research there occurred a problem with the adop- tion of a relevant research period, so the phenomena described in the theoretical econometric models were

carried out under comparable conditions of economic decision-making by business entities, i.e. in a situa- tion when the distortions resulting from a centrally planned economy ceased to be relevant for the course of economic processes at the level of aggregated values.

In addition, it was necessary to draw attention to the specificities of the economy, under which these models were created. They are frequently based on statistical data from countries with a far different level of eco- nomic development than the country the model is to refer to (Zienkowski, 2002).

The European Commission’s Report of October 1999 showed that Poland (Ćwikliński, 2000) was evalu- ated as a positively developing market economy, which was confirmed by the observed changes in ownership structure, legal and institutional changes correspond- ing to the rules of market economy. The European Commission experts confirmed that the Polish econ- omy is able to compete with other countries character- ized by higher levels of development.

Accordingly, the authors decided to adopt the years 1998-2008 as the study period, assuming that in 1998 the next phase of construction of a market economy was completed.

The starting point for research is the preliminary analysis of changes in the GDP, the net values of fixed assets and employment in the Polish economy (pre- sented on the figure 2).

 

‐5,00 0,00 5,00 10,00 15,00 20,00

1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 employment  net value of fixed assets GDP

Figure 2. The rate of change of GDP, the net values of fixed assets and employment in 1998-2008 (compared to the previous period in %, current prices)

Note. Based on data file available from http:// www.stat.gov.pl, access on 08.12.2010

(7)

In the years 1998-2008, the average employment rate in the national economy showed some fluctuations.

Until 2005, the average number of employees had been systematically declining. In subsequent years a system- atic growth could be observed. In 2008, the average level of employment in the national economy was similar to that of 1998 adopted in this study as the base year and amounted to nearly 9,900 thousand people.

In 1999-2004, both GDP growth and the net value of fixed assets were characterized by a significant increase.

By contrast, employment fell systematically. One can venture to say that in the years covered by the study, the GDP growth was largely affected by the increased investment in physical capital, which probably contrib- uted to the further restructuring of employment.

In 1999, the pace of GDP growth and the net values of fixed assets were approximate and both reached over 10%. Whereas, the average level of employment de- creased by 2.3%. It is worth noting year 2002, when the pace of economic growth was 3.7% and was lower by nearly 2 p.p. than the net value of fixed assets amount- ing to 5.6%. The average level of employment in the year under study decreased by more than 3%. It must be noted that expenditures in fixed assets bring effect only in a later period, which may translate into an ad- justment in the GDP growth in the future.

In 2005-2006, the pace of GDP growth was higher than the pace of growth of the net value of fixed as- sets and the average employment level. In 2007-2008, both the pace of GDP growth and the net values of fixed assets were similar and, for example in 2007, they reached over 10%. On the other hand, in 2008 a simi- lar pace of GDP and net assets value growth were ob- served, but they were lower than in the previous year – it amounted to more than 8% – while the average employment rate increased to 5%.

Before estimating the parameters of the Cobb- Douglas function the correlation coefficients were cal- culated showing the strength of relations between the independent and the dependent variables. The analysis of correlation coefficients suggests that in 1991-2008, there was a negative average correlation between GDP and labour and a strong and positive correlation be- tween GDP and capital. A detailed listing of correla- tion coefficients is given in the table 1.

The negative relationship between the GDP and em- ployment confirms the presence of strong structural

changes in the Polish economy arising not only from the technological and structural changes consistent with the theory of Clark (1940); Fourastie (1954) and Fisher (1939), but also of structural changes arising from economic transition. In order to eliminate the influence of the last of the factors on the course of eco- nomic processes the period of research was limited to the years 1998-2008.

In order to determine the flexibility of production against labour and capital in the period under study, both the static function, given in formula (1) as well as dynamic, presented by equation (4) were estimated.

Table 2 presents the results of the estimations of the static Cobb-Douglas function for Poland in the pe- riod 1998-2008. Analyzing the data in table 2, we can consider all the parameters as statistically significant at the significance level of 0.10. The high value of the determination coefficient indicates that over 99% of the total variability in production was explained by the proposed model, and Godfrey statistic allows infer- ences about the absence of significant autocorrelation of the random component.

Therefore, we say that 1% increase in capital re- sulted during the analysed period in the increase of production of 1.18%, provided the employment level was maintained. While 1% increase in employment contributed to the increase of production by 0.29%, provided the capital level was stable. This means that the production growth was mainly the result of capital growth. In this case, the changes are explained by the neoclassical theory of convergence. Table 3 presents the results of the estimation of the dynamic Cobb- Douglas function according to formula (4). The analy- sis of the results leads to the conclusion that the coef- ficients of production flexibility against capital (α1) and labour (α2) can be considered statistically significant at the significance level of 0.10. Whereas, the param- eter describing the technological progress at the level of 0.112. The estimated econometric model explains 99.4% of the total variability of production in the anal- ysed period and is free from the autocorrelation of the random component.

Interpreting the results of the evaluation, we say that in the analysed period 1% increase in capital mea- sured with the net value of fixed assets contributed to an 0.65% increase of the GDP, provided the stability of employment was maintained. While a 1% increase

(8)

in average employment in the economy caused the GDP growth of 0.27%, with stable capital levels. In the period in question, the average annual GDP growth amounted to 3.25% due to technological progress.

This means that the main factor behind the economic growth in 1998-2008 was the technological progress taking place in the economy.

Conclusions

Both the static and the dynamic function describe well the relations between production on the one hand and capital and labour on the other. In both cases, the la-

bour factor was statistically less significant than the capital factor.

Changes in the net value of fixed assets (capital) influenced the GDP growth stronger than changes in employment. This follows from the fact that in the years 1998-2008 there was a low negative correlation between GDP and labour, with a strong and positive correlation between GDP and capital. The obtained results confirm the specificity of the national economy undergoing structural changes requiring in the first place increased investments in fixed assets and replac- ing labour-consuming technologies with labour-sav- Table 1. Pearson correlation coefficients

Table 2. The results of estimation of the static production function

Table 3. The results of estimation the dynamic production function

Note. Own study based on Central Statistical Office data and the MFit software.

Note. Own study based on Central Statistical Office data and the MFit software.

dependent variable Independent variables

L C

Y -0.382 0.996

lnL lnC

lnY -0.470 0.989

Parameter / Verification measure Parameter assessment Value of the T statistic Critical level of significance

α1 1.176 29.935 0.000

α2 0.288 1.864 0.099

R2 0.991 x x

F-stat [Godfrey test] 0.461 x 0.519

Parameter / Verification measure Parameter assessment Value of the T statistic Critical level of significance

α1 0.653 2.252 0.059

α2 0.268 1.962 0.091

α3 0.032 1.820 0.112

R2 0.994 x x

F-stat [Godfrey test] 0.209 x 0.663

(9)

ing ones. The dynamic Cobb-Douglas function shows that the GDP growth during a given period deter- mined technological progress. It probably contributed to changes in employment levels (decrease) resulting from the increase in labour productivity.

References

Aiyar, S., & Dalgaard, C. J. (2009). Accounting for productivity: Is it OK to assume that the world is Cobb-Douglas? Journal of Macroeconomics, 31(2), 290-303.

Bałtowski, M., & Miszewski, M. (2007). Transformacja gospodarcza w Polsce. [Economic transformation in Poland].Warszawa: PWE.

Ben-David, D. (1993). Equalizing exchange: Trade liberalization and income convergence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 3, 653-679.

Berman, E., Bound, J. & Machin, S. (1998).

Implications of Skill-Biased Technological Change: International Evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(4), 1245-79.

Bukowski, M., & Dyrda, S.. (2009). Makroekonomia procesu zmiany technologicznej [Macroeconomics of the process of technological change] (chapter 2). In M. Bukowski and J. Zawistowski (Eds.), Zmiana technologiczna na polskim rynku pracy [Technological change in the Polish labor market].

Retrieved from http://analizy.mpips.gov.pl/

index.php/raporty-i-publikacje-topmenu-58/32- opracowania-tematyczne.html

Burda, M., & Wyplosz, Ch. (2000). Makroekonomia.

[Macroeconomics]. Warszawa: PWE.

Caselli, F. & Tenreyro, S. (2005). Is Poland The Next Spain. NBER Working Papers, 11045, 5-10.

Clark, C. (1940). The Conditions of Economic Progress.

3rd ed. London, UK: Macmillan.

Ćwikliński, H. (2000). Polityka gospodarcza. [Economic policy]. Gdańsk: Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Gdańskiego.

Fisher, A. G. B. (1939). Production, Primary, Secondary and Tertiary. The Economic Records, 15(1), 24-38.

Fourastie, J. (1954). Die grosse Hoffnung des zwanzigsten Jahrhunderts. [The great hope of the twentieth century]. Köln-Deutz.

Główny Urząd Statystyczny. (2001) – (2009). Roczniki Statystyczne RP. [Statistical Yearbooks of Poland].

Warszawa: GUS.

Jalava, J., Pohjola, M., Ripatti, A., & Vilmunen, J.

(2006). Biased Technical Change and Capital – Labour Substitution In Finland 1902 – 2003.

Journal of Macroeconomics, 6(8), 1-15.

Miller, E. (2008). An assessment of CES and Cobb- Douglas production functions. Congressional Budget Office Working Paper, 05, 1-20.

Mulat, T. (1980). Capital - Labor Substitution in the Ethiopian Manufacturing Industries. Developing Economies, 18(3), 275-587.

Pońsko, P. (2000). Optymalizacja dynamiczna wzrostu gospodarczego. [Dynamic Optimization of economic Growth ].Warszawa: Elipsa –WSHiFM.

Ripatti, A., & Vilmunen, J. (2001). Declining Labor Share – Evidence of a Change in the Underlying Production Technology?. Bank of Finland Discussion Papers, 10, 1-14.

Tokarski, T. (2003). Specyfikacja funkcji produkcji a równowaga długookresowego wzrostu gospodarczego. [Specification of production functions and the balance long-term economic growth]. Ekonomista, 3, 341-363.

Tokarski, T. (2010). Przestrzenne zróżnicowanie łącznej produktywności czynników produkcji w Polsce.

[Spatial variation of total productivity factors in Poland].Gospodarka Narodowa, 3, 23-39.

Weller, J. (2001). Economic reforms, growth and employment: Labor markets in Latin America and Caribbean. Chile: ECLAC.

Wojtyna, A. (Ed.). (2010). Zależności między produktywnością, dochodami i zatrudnieniem w krajach na różnym poziomie rozwoju.

[Relationships between productivity, income and employment in countries at different stages of development.] Warszawa: PWE.

Zienkowski, L. (2002). Efekty transformacji i perspektywy rozwoju gospodarki polskiej. [Effects of transformation and development prospects of the Polish economy]. In A. Welfe (Ed), Modele i polityka makroekonomiczna [Macroeconomic Models and Policy] (165-189). Warszawa: PWE.

(10)

Cytaty

Powiązane dokumenty

For proving that equality of chances enrich the definition of human capital, the own research findings were used, with support from other empirical studies, data from

However, this research has led to other insights such as the possible relation between the number of PC’s and the region where the airline is stationed and that during a recession

Można jednak podejmować szereg działań stymulujących rozwój inicjatyw klastrowych, co może przyczynić się w znacznym stopniu do ich wzrostu, a co za tym idzie

Jak wskazano wyżej, współcześnie nie jest to wyznaczone tylko w ramach danego państwa, ale wymaga dostosowania się do międzynarodo- wych ustaleń, co głównie dotyczy

„R ola specjacji oraz dobrej praktyki laboratoryjnej w analizie żywności” przedstaw ił zasadnicze problem y związane z analizą żywności oraz nowe kryteria

Тим часом, враховуючи світові тенденції, перспективними напрямами розвитку та вдосконалення діяльності університету на середню та довготривалу перспективу є:

(including a large number of thin black- painted boards with holes pierced through the ends) is a group of elements originating from the furnishings of the church and monastery:

IRK-MC [Cynarski 2007], AIESEP jest skrótem od francuskiej nazwy: Association Internationale des Ecoles Supérieures d’Education Physique, czyli jest skrótem nazwy