• Nie Znaleziono Wyników

Exploring standards consortium survival in high tech industries

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Exploring standards consortium survival in high tech industries"

Copied!
11
0
0

Pełen tekst

(1)

Delft University of Technology

Exploring standards consortium survival in high tech industries

The effects of commitment and internal competition

Kamps, Xavier; de Vries, Henk; van de Kaa, Geerten

DOI

10.1016/j.csi.2017.02.002

Publication date

2017

Document Version

Final published version

Published in

Computer Standards and Interfaces

Citation (APA)

Kamps, X., de Vries, H., & van de Kaa, G. (2017). Exploring standards consortium survival in high tech

industries: The effects of commitment and internal competition. Computer Standards and Interfaces, 52,

105-113. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.csi.2017.02.002

Important note

To cite this publication, please use the final published version (if applicable).

Please check the document version above.

Copyright

Other than for strictly personal use, it is not permitted to download, forward or distribute the text or part of it, without the consent of the author(s) and/or copyright holder(s), unless the work is under an open content license such as Creative Commons. Takedown policy

Please contact us and provide details if you believe this document breaches copyrights. We will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim.

This work is downloaded from Delft University of Technology.

(2)

Green Open Access added to TU Delft Institutional Repository

'You share, we take care!' - Taverne project

https://www.openaccess.nl/en/you-share-we-take-care

Otherwise as indicated in the copyright section: the publisher

is the copyright holder of this work and the author uses the

Dutch legislation to make this work public.

(3)

Contents lists available atScienceDirect

Computer Standards & Interfaces

journal homepage:www.elsevier.com/locate/csi

Exploring standards consortium survival in high tech industries: The e

ffects

of commitment and internal competition

Xavier Kamps

a

, Henk de Vries

a

, Geerten van de Kaa

b,⁎

aRotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University, Burgemeester Oudlaan 50, 3062PA Rotterdam, The Netherlands bFaculty of Technology, Policy, and Management, Delft University of Technology, Jaffalaan 5, 2628BX Delft, The Netherlands

A R T I C L E I N F O

Keywords: Standards Standards consortia Commitment Competition Survival analysis

A B S T R A C T

Standards consortia develop technical standards or specifications and promote these to reach market dominance. Research on competing standards has explored eitherfirm-level or standard-level factors, but the dynamics of standards consortia and their survival have remained largely understudied. The pre- and post-competitive phase of standards consortia supporting standards may better explain why certain standard-setting efforts fail where others succeed. In this empirical study we operationalize the concepts of internal standards consortium competition and standards consortium commitment, and analyse the effects of these concepts on the survival of high-tech standards consortia. Wefind that the influx of new strategic members throughout the years is beneficial for the longevity of the consortium. In addition, we find that standards consortia possibly constrain the entrance of new members if their existing members have a multitude of other concurrent standards consortium memberships.

1. Introduction

An extensive body of research has gone into exploring and explaining the factors that influence certain technological standards to become dominant in the marketplace at the expense of competing standards [10,31]. In recent decades the cost and complexity of innovations have led to increased collaborations in developing, pro-moting and maintaining standards through standards consortia. Individual firms may no longer have sufficient resources to develop these standards and make them dominant in the market place on their own[44].

Much research has gone into interfirm standards battles and firm survival e.g. [9,34,33,39], but the dynamics and survival of standards consortia have remained an empirically understudied phenomenon. This paper aims to extend existing literature by exploring the effects of commitment and internal competition from a consortium-level per-spective. The focus on standards consortia survival may also provide an alternative measurement of standardization success to a standard's success in the marketplace, as it is sometimes hard to determine the exact market of a standard. This is particularly true in high-tech industries where many standards compete with other standards on different aspects for different applications, but collaborate on others (e.g. USB and Bluetooth).

Standards consortia allow their members more control over

stan-dardization efforts, outputs, and strategy than formal standardization bodies. In many cases, the procedures for voting and decision-making in standards consortia are handled with informally[17]. Suchflexibility in dealing with rules and procedures allows members more freedom in turning their economic or political power intofirm-level benefits[39]. This makes standards consortia prone to internal competition, just like any other collaboration betweenfirms[46]. A closer look into internal standards consortium competition may therefore better explain why certain standard-setting efforts fail where others succeed.

Furthermore, the degree of commitment offirms to the standard-setting process has been identified to affect the outcome of the process [38,40]. Whereas intuitively understood, further explorations of the role of commitment in standardization are lacking. The membership dynamics of inter-firm collaborations and the termination of these collaborations have been well-studied in strategic management litera-ture (e.g.[25]). This study will therefore draw from that literature and combine these insights with insights from the dominant design and standardization literature in order to ensure a sound theoretical underpinning. The combination of these streams of literature allows us to hypothesize the expected impact of internal standards consortium competition and commitment on standards consortium survival. These expected relationships constitute our conceptual model. In order to test these, we then develop measurements for standards consortium competition and commitment, as these have not been measured in a

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.csi.2017.02.002

Received 27 October 2016; Received in revised form 6 February 2017; Accepted 8 February 2017

Corresponding author.

E-mail address:g.vandekaa@tudelft.nl(G. van de Kaa).

Computer Standards & Interfaces 52 (2017) 105–113

Available online 13 February 2017

0920-5489/ © 2017 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

(4)

similar research-setting in the past. Next, we will introduce the research methodology and research choices made, followed by the findings of this study. The implications of the research findings will follow in the discussion section, after which we will give recommenda-tions for further research and summarize ourfindings in the conclud-ing chapter.

2. Theory and hypotheses

The degree of commitment to a standard influences its chances of reaching success [36,48]. Commitment typically manifests itself through long-term development efforts and sound technical choices surrounding a certain technological trajectory aiming at long term-rather than short-term gains[26]. Indeed, the willingness of members to commit to a certain standards consortium through active participa-tion is an important determinant of successful standardizaparticipa-tion[43]. However, it can be problematic when members are too committed to a certain technological trajectory. In their study on the battle between two competing e-purse systems in the Netherlands, De Vries and Hendrikse [8] found that the supporters of Chipper continued to pursue the highly costly development of their technology, despite changes in market conditions that strongly reduced their chances of success.

Commitment is often used to describe the actions of individuals

[13], but individual actions serve as the“building blocks of a firm's competitive behaviour” ([18], p. 298). The collective commitment of firms in a standards consortium is comprised of the commitment of the individual representatives of thesefirms, because changes in amount of afirm's individuals committed to a standards consortium commonly follow strategic changes of the employer [11]. Such changes are avoided when these individuals“are able to convey the value of being involved in a consortium to their top management” ([48], p.30), because that leads to a realignment of commitment between indivi-duals and thefirms they represent.

González and Guillén[13]mention three dimensions of commit-ment that are commonly identified in the literature: continuance commitment, affective commitment, and normative commitment. Continuance commitment relates to the commitment individuals can have because they have little or few alternatives available, making continuation of the current course of action the only salient one. Arguably this type of commitment doesn’t truly represent commitment because a lack of alternatives suggests it is rather a dimension of necessity than of commitment. This leads González and Guillén[13]to interpret this dimension as a technical-economic dimension of com-mitment. The necessity to follow a certain course of action can be seen as voluntary, based on calculated behaviour that leads from a maximal expected obtainable value through that course of action (Ibid.).

When thefirms within a standards consortium collectively decide to limit their number of concurrent standards consortium memberships, it may increase their commitment to the course of action of the standards consortium and ultimately increase the chance for standards consortium survival. Holding multiple memberships of standards consortia during standards battles is a sign of early avoidance of commitment and could affect the outcome of the battle [5]. Firms may maximize expected benefits from standardization through the member-ship of multiple standards consortia, but this is a sign of decreased technical-economic commitment to each single standards consortium they are a member of for two reasons.

First,firms with a multitude of concurrent standards consortium memberships can spread the risk of standardization failure over multiple standards consortia. The failure of a single standards con-sortium may affect these firms less than firms with fewer standards consortium memberships. Firms with fewer standards consortium memberships are therefore more tied to the course of action of their standards consortia because premature disbandment has a greater effect on the value they can obtain from all memberships in a given

year.

Second, firms with multiple concurrent standards consortium memberships may not be able to devote the same amount of resources to each standards consortium than firms with fewer memberships. Simply because “commitment inputs are difficult or impossible to redeploy to another exchange in the same form” ([15], p.79).

Standards consortia may also benefit from members that are less committed in terms of number of concurrent memberships. Concurrent standards consortium participations influence the composition and structure of a firm's network and increase their influence in the standard-setting outcome [2]. The increased sharing of ideas with firms they are connected to may lead to the generation of new technical knowledge[47]that is shared across standards consortia. In addition, firms with greater alliance experience often have a dedicated alliance function or alliance management capabilities which means they have more knowledge about how to successfully manage an alliance. This not only leads to better knowledge dispersion, but also to a higher survival of alliances [28].

In summary, partaking in a number of alternative technologies through alternative standards consortia may benefit these individual technologies and standards consortia as consortia allow their members to share ideas and develop diverse knowledge via the experience of their members (Weiss, 1993 as cited by[46].). However, remaining flexible to alternative technologies may eventually come at the risk of standards consortia members diluting their commitment to a given technology trajectory [30] and threaten the standards consortia survival. We therefore propose:

Hypothesis 1:. There is an inverted u-shaped relationship between the number of standards consortium memberships per firm and standards consortium survival.

The second dimension of commitment is affective commitment, which relates to the desire to continue in a certain course of action. This desire stems from acknowledging shared goals between the individual and the organization[13]. The desire to be loyal is included in this dimension of commitment, while the (moral) obligation to be loyal is commonly included in thefinal dimension of commitment: normative commitment. This third dimension differs from the other dimensions in that it is not an emotive, but a rational and moral commitment to a certain course of action because of an individual's identification with and acceptance of organizational objectives [13]. Previous scholars have criticized the distinction between affective and normative com-mitment because they have found a lack of discriminant validity between the two (Ibid.). We will therefore limit our focus to the affective dimension of commitment and the already discussed con-tinuance commitment as technical-economic dimension of commit-ment.

Zhao et al.[46]find that a member of a standards consortium is more likely to continue its membership if the consortium goals are aligned with its own strategic goals. Membership continuity is an acknowledgement that the goals between the standards consortium members and the consortium are, at least to a large extent, aligned. Membership continuity can therefore be seen as an indicator for on-going commitment and participation. Membership continuity in stan-dards consortia allows members to use networks more effectively[27]

because repeated collaborative problem-solving within the consortium leads to respect, trust and common values among all members. Departure from standards consortia could stem from an avoidance of (early stage) commitment [5], be the result of a change in strategic focus of a member, disagreement over the focus or scope of the consortium, or finding the membership costs too high [12]. Membership retention is important for R & D consortia and standards consortia, because the departure of a member means a loss of monetary and technical resources (Ibid.; [46]). Membership retention could therefore be important for the survival of standards consortia.

Standards consortia may try to limit the entrance of new members

X. Kamps et al. Computer Standards & Interfaces 52 (2017) 105–113

(5)

to avoid fragmenting a standard and its implementation, preferring a uniform presence to be effective[44]. An ever-changing heterogeneous group of members leads to more heterogeneity of interests, which is detrimental to the standard setting process[23]because it may lead to scope creep[4].

Changes in alliances (i.e. instability or turnover) are oftentimes a result of adverse developments and a precursor for unplanned and premature disbandment of alliances[7]. Such changes can therefore be seen as a proxy for poor alliance performance (Ibid.). We therefore propose:

Hypothesis 2:. Membership continuity within the standards consortium positively influences standards consortium survival.

Members of joint ventures that have alternative joint ventures through which to reach certain goals might have a higher likelihood to leave a certain joint venture[25]. Greve et al.[14]find that the effects of outside options are particularly strong when the alternatives offer more market complementarity. Similar dynamics may play a role in standards consortia, in that the number of outside memberships of current members may negatively impact membership continuity. In addition, high membership continuity might lead members to lower their outside options because they trust the members within the consortium and are subsequently more committed to the standards consortium. We therefore propose:

Hypothesis 3a. : The number of standards consortium memberships per firm negatively influences membership continuity within the standards consortium.

Hypothesis 3b. : Membership continuity within the standards consortium negatively influences the number of standards consortium memberships perfirm.

“Competition is the rule of the market and there is no exception for strategic alliances” ([7], p. 85). This is no different for standards consortia, as the ability forfirms to reach agreements with other firms in the midst of technological battles depends on the relative power of each actor and the level of cooperation versus competition [34]. Competition is the pursuit of one's own interests at the expense of the interests of others, whereas cooperation is about the pursuit of the common benefits (Ibid.). The degree of competition among members within (vertical) standards consortia affects members’ contributions and success of these standards consortia ([46]; Brock, 1975, as cited by

[2]), just as in any collaboration between multiple parties[46]. Whilefirms typically tend to avoid close rivals within a standards consortium to gain a competitive advantage over these rivals [2], partners within such collaborations are likely to be indirect or potential future competitors[7]. The (strategic) members of a standards con-sortium may sign non-disclosure agreements to ensure knowledge can and will be shared without it leaking to the marketplace. This is particularly important when the technological advancements being shared and worked on are at too early stage to be patented[29]. Such sharing may come at the cost of increased internal competition among members that try to absorb knowledge faster than their partners within the same collaborative constellation ([7]; Zhang et al., 2010). High internal competition could lead to opportunistic behaviour, which is detrimental to inter-firm trust and can ‘seriously undermine the basis for successful alliances’ ([7], p. 78). Because“those alliance types that are skewed towards competition [.] and short-term orientation [that] are more likely to be terminated through dissolution”[6], we propose: Hypothesis 4:. Internal standards consortium competition is negatively related to standards consortium survival.

Fig. 1provides an overview of the hypotheses. 3. Research methodology

For the purpose of this research we use the Actor-Network-Standard database developed by Van de Kaa[38]and extended since

then. This database contains membership information of standards consortia. Our unit of analysis is the standards consortium. Standards consortia are represented by the highest organizational unit, mostly Board members each representing a particular firm. Membership information was collected through a retrospective analysis of archived websites in the Internet Archive (webarchive.com). We have taken a subset of 69 standards consortia with corporate membership, founded in the period between 1999 and 2010 and not active prior to that time. Our sample is spread among the industry categories information technology (IT), consumer electronics (CE), telecommunications (TE), and home automation (HA). In supplementalfile 1 the total set of standards organizations is presented including the industry cate-gories they represent.

We have used the Compustat and the Thomson One Banker database to accompany membership information with revenue data for all individual memberfirms through the years. We have extended the revenue information available in these databases with revenue data from SEC-filings as well as annual reports, company rankings (e.g. Deloitte fast 50), and (archived) corporate websites. A few largefirms did not disclose the revenue information for all subsequent years. We have used the‘linear trend at point’ procedure to regress the existing series of values to predict the missing values[45]as available revenue data for thesefirms indicated linear revenue fluctuations. 25 out of 3,781 person-periodfile rows have been computed by the linear trend at point procedure. Each row in our database represents a single active year of one of the 69 standards consortia, totalling 409 unique rows.

We have argued that the number of standards consortium member-ships per firm is an indicator of continuance commitment as a technical-economic dimension of commitment. We measure this con-cept through the median number of standards consortia perfirm in order to avoid bias fromfirms with relatively many or relatively few standards consortium memberships in consortia with smaller member numbers on the average number of standards consortium member-ships.

Membership continuity within the standards consortium has been identified as an operationalization of the affective dimension of commitment. We base our measurement of membership continuity on the measurement of membership stability by Basehart [3]: the percentage of total membership of members from a standards con-sortium in any given year also member of that concon-sortium in the preceding year.

The influx of new members lowers membership continuity regard-less of the continuity of current members of the consortium. In order to determine the effect of the influx of new members on membership continuity, we also adopt an alternative measure of membership continuity. This alternative membership continuity is the percentage of members in a given year that are also a member in the following

Fig. 1. Conceptual model of determinants of standards consortium survival. X. Kamps et al. Computer Standards & Interfaces 52 (2017) 105–113

(6)

year. In case of termination, there is no t+1 year to draw the number of members from. We therefore lag membership continuity for one year in order to have measurements for each year standards consortia are active. The founding year is also considered to be the base year at 100%, just as for the regular membership continuity measure. We have considered mergers and acquisitions of fellow members as a continua-tion of efforts, in order to have these not influence the membership continuity measures.

The two alternative measures of membership continuity are com-puted using the same data and are therefore expected to be highly correlated, we shall therefore test these in separate models in order to evaluate their effect on standards consortia survival.

The degree of internal competition within consortia can be assessed by comparing objective measures of collaborators such as profitability and firm size[7]. We believe an adjusted Herfindahl Index is well-suited for this purpose. This index is often used to look at the relative size of individualfirms in a market and the competition among all firms in a certain market. The Herfindahl Index is measured as follows:

H= s s N i =1 2

N is the number offirms in the standards consortium, and siis the

market share offirm i. We consider the focal standards consortium as a singular market in which each member tries to influence the specifica-tions of the standard. The market power is the combined annual revenue of the standards consortium members on which the market shares are based. The Herfindahl Index turns the objective firm-level measures into a measure that can be compared across years and across standards consortia. An additional benefit of using the Herfindahl Index is that this measure has been used in previous literature in a wide variety of contexts. Generalized interpretations of the Herfindahl Index exist, which makes interpretation of the index easier. Herfindahl Index measures close to 0 indicate high internal competition whereas measures close to 10.000 are indicative of a general lack of internal competition.

At any given moment, standards consortia might continue their efforts or they might disband. Such terminations are not necessarily a result of failed standard-setting, because these may be planned[21]. We have therefore assessed every single termination and when a clear success was mentioned, we do not consider the termination as failure. This makes the failures in our data reflect terminations due to unsuccessful operations rather than planned terminations, in line with Das and Teng[7]. We have also assessed mergers and acquisitions of standards consortia, because not all unplanned events are failures. Many standards consortia have merged because of overlap in activities, making the merger a strategic and mutual decision rather than a failure.

Acquisitions in which the acquired standards consortia are still active at time of acquisition and the technological trajectory is pursued after acquisition are also not considered failures, they seem to have similar underlying strategic motives as mergers. Standards consortia that become dormant without notice are also not considered failures. We limit the possibilities for spurious effects by this conservative approach to failures. In our data we identify 20 failing standards consortia.

We apply survival analysis to determine the effects of the number of standards consortium memberships perfirm, membership continuity and internal standards consortium competition on standards consor-tium survival. Because the factors under study are time-dependent, we use the Cox proportional-hazards regression model with time-varying covariates, also known as the extended Cox model[19,24]. This model is a ‘safe choice’ compared to parametric models as it gives reliable results without the danger that an ill-suited model is chosen [19]. Terminations, mergers and acquisitions disregarded as failures are considered censored exits and are thus still used, because data about

these standards consortia up until inactivity may still contain valuable information for statistical inferences.

Following Vittinghoff and McCulloch[43], we will relax the rule of thumb for each predictor variable (EPV) for testing our full model. We will use backwards variable selection at the p > .20 level [22] for refitting our model. This allows us to address potential residual confounding, but also to limit type II error by increasing the EPV. We use backwards selection rather than forward selection because it reduces the chances of excluding negatively confounded variables from the model[36].

We include the control variable Year of foundation: the year a standards consortium was founded or first became active. Well-established consortia have better management effectiveness perception than relatively newer ones, possibly due to their experience in mana-ging multilateral cooperation [48], which means that the year a standards consortium was founded affects standards consortium survival[38]. The full model is written as:

logh t α t β NumberOfMembershipsPerFirm t β MembershipContinuity t β HerfindahlIndex t β YearOfFoundation ( ) = ( ) + ( ) + ( ) + ( ) + i i i i 1 1 1 2 2 3 3 4 4

Where α is the constant term and the hazard h for standards consortium i at time t depends on the values of the predictor variables. 4. Results

The average (arithmetic mean) of years per standards consortium recorded is 5.92 years (time-to-failure and censored exits), ranging from one year to the full scope of 11 years of this study. The survival function S(t) in Fig. 2 depicts the number of years the standards consortia survive in our database.

The number of standards consortium memberships perfirm ranges from 1 to 20 and averages at 5, see Table 1. Both measures of membership continuity range from 12.50% to 100% with a mean approaching 90%.

The maximum value measured is also the median value for both measurements, indicating that values are extremely skewed towards one side. This may lead to difficulties in determining an effect between the degree of membership continuity on the survival of standards consortia. We therefore include a dichotomous measurement for membership continuity computed with the median split procedure. This procedure is justified to accompany highly skewed data[32], and may help to discriminate between standards consortia with member-ship continuity and standards consortia that havefluctuations in any given year. The univariate regression results are reported inTable 2.

We use the Breslow-Peto approximation and report the regression

Fig. 2. Graphical survival function output.

X. Kamps et al. Computer Standards & Interfaces 52 (2017) 105–113

(7)

(beta) coefficients rather than hazard ratios. Model 1 is the base model with the control variable. The control variable of year of foundation does not seem to influence a standards consortium to disband. We test the proportional hazards assumption in models 2–10. These models include the independent variables with and without their interaction term with time under tvc. Significant values under tvc indicate a violation of the proportional hazards assumption, in which case the interaction term should be included in the multivariate analysis[24].

The test of the proportional hazards assumption for the interval measure of year of foundation and the dichotomous measure of

membership continuity cannot be done through regression. We have conducted the Schoenfeld residuals test with p-values of 0.4290 and 0.2232 for the year of foundation and the dichotomous measure of membership continuity. This indicates that there is no violation of the hazard assumption for these variables (Ibid.).

To testHypothesis 1wefit the mean-centered variable of number of memberships per firm together with its quadratic term. Model 12 (Table 3) shows that there is no violation of the hazard assumption for the squared term number of memberships perfirm. Model 13 shows no significant u-shaped relationship could be determined between the number of memberships per firm and standards consortia survival without including the other covariates.

Table 4reports models with all covariates to be used for backwards variable selection. Models 14–15 represent the initial full models with and without the mean-centered and quadratic terms of number of memberships per firm. Models 16–17 represent the models with alternative measures for membership continuity.

Comparing the models 14–17 with the univariate regression, we see that the Herfindahl Measure p-value dropped in value compared to Model 9. This may be a result of lower EPV (3–5) compared to EPV = 20 in the univariate regression. Lower EPV's increase the occurrence of type II error[43]. Another possible explanation is multicollinearity, which is known to cause very unstable p-values [42]. We test for multicollinearity by looking at the matrix of correlations between the coefficients of our full Model 14 reported inTable 5 [16].

Table 1

Descriptive statistics.

Variable N Min. Max. Mean Median Std. Dev. Number of memberships perfirm 409 1.00 20.00 5.00 3.5 4.46 Membership continuity 409 12.50% 100.00% 87.68% 100% 19.18% Alternative membership continuity 409 12.50% 100.00% 89.34% 100% 16.99% Herfindahl Index 409 375.62 10,000.00 3,542.33 2,772.01 2,394.85 Year of foundation 409 1999 2010 2002.21 2006 2.62 Table 2

Results of univariate extended Cox regression.

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 main βYearOfFoundation −.0103328 (.0868797) βNumberOfMembershipsPerFirm −.1021232 .0003572 (.0661429) (.1033228) βMembershipContinuity 2.482737 −7.097752 (2.549561) (5.208359) βAlternativeMembershipContinuity −.8920997 −3.541716 (.9455057) (2.337179) βMembershipContinuityDichotomous 1.869721*** (.625577) βHerfindahlIndex .0001897*** .000161 (.0000732) (.0001104) tvc βNumberOfMembershipsPerFirm(t) −.0285852 (.0249676) βMembershipContinuity(t) −.0285852** (.0249676) βAlternativeMembershipContinuity(t) .7382074 (.5958915) βHerfindahlIndex(t) 0.00000688 (.0000194) No. observations 409 409 409 409 409 409 409 409 409 409 No. Subjects 69 69 69 69 69 69 69 69 69 69

No. Failures (i.e. consortia terminations)

20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20 20

Log pseudolikelihood −73.58320 −72.22681 −71.91582 −72.18540 −68.7518 −73.22552 −72.48638 −67.29896 −70.96616 −70.94245 Prob > chi2 .9053 .1226 .1721 .3302 0.0467 0.3454 0.3021 0.0028 0.0095 0.0366

Variables in tvc equation interacted with time. Values for the variables are beta coefficients.

Values in parentheses are cluster-robust standard errors. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10

X. Kamps et al. Computer Standards & Interfaces 52 (2017) 105–113

(8)

The correlation between Membership continuity and the time-interacted term is not surprising, since it was purposefully added to the model. However, we alsofind proof for multicollinearity, in that the correlation between the Herfindahl Measure and number of

member-ships perfirm is higher than .50. Since Number of memberships per firm has not been significant in the univariate analysis, and does not pass the p > .20 level from our proposed selection strategy. This is also the case for the mean-centered measure and its quadratic term,

Table 3

Results of extended Cox regression.

11 12 13 main βCenteredNumberOfMembershipsPerFirm −.0976819 (.078062) βCenteredNumberOfMembershipsPerFirmSquared −.009758 −.0094822 −.001529 (.0070605) (.0119288) (.00935) tvc βCenteredNumberOfMembershipsPerFirm(t) βCenteredNumberOfMembershipsPerFirmSquared(t) −.0000813 (.0032508) No. observations 409 409 409 No. Subjects 69 69 69

No. Failures (i.e. consortia terminations) 20 20 20

Log pseudolikelihood −73.00256 −72.22039 −73.00249

Prob > chi2 .1670 .3724 .2971

Variables in tvc equation interacted with time. Values for the variables are beta coefficients.

Values in parentheses are cluster-robust standard errors. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10 + p < 0.20

Table 4

Results of extended Cox regression.

14 15 16 17 main βYearOfFoundation .0062317 .0093824 .0260141 .004032 (.0909164) (.08971) (.0915487) (.0900401) βNumberOfMembershipsPerFirm −.0675912 −.0339117 −.0858579 (.0725435) (.0677367) (.072054) βCenteredNumberOfMembershipsPerFirm −.0675912 −.0419062 (.10031) βCenteredNumberOfMembershipsPerFirmSquared −.0054935 (.0725435) (.0092936) βMembershipContinuity −6.552466+ −6.591869+ (4.721289) (4.760144) βAlternativeMembershipContinuity −.20562 (.83014) βMembershipContinuityDichotomous 1.867073*** (.6254556) βHerfindahlIndex .0001482+ .0001639+ .0001622* .000094 (.0000947) (.0001035) (.0000836) (.0000858) tvc βMembershipContinuity(t) 3.479139** 3.457901** (1.568153) (1.565599) No. observations 409 409 409 409 No. Subjects 69 69 69 69

No. Failures (i.e. consortia terminations) 20 20 20 20 Log pseudolikelihood −65.74390 −65.66966 −70.80661 −64.91666

Prob > chi2 .0026 .0066 .1338 .0001

Variables in tvc equation interacted with time. Values for the variables are beta coefficients.

Values in parentheses are cluster-robust standard errors. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10 + p < 0.20

X. Kamps et al. Computer Standards & Interfaces 52 (2017) 105–113

(9)

meaning that we will eliminate these variables from the model. Wefind no sufficient evidence for a relationship between the number of memberships perfirm and standards consortia survival (H1).

No other significant effects from the univariate analysis are attenuated in the multivariate analysis and no effects have become significant in the multivariate analysis. This means that we will also eliminate year of foundation and the alternative membership continu-ity measure, for their p-values are also greater than .20. We will keep the Herfindahl measure, for it passes the test in 3 out of 4 models presented inTable 4. The regression results of the refitted models are

reported inTable 6.

We are unable to determine an effect between the degree of membership continuity and standards consortia survival (Model 18). We do, however,find that absolute membership continuity negatively influences standards consortia survival (Model 19) Standards consortia that do not open for new entrants have a 76.3% higher probability of disbandment. This is in contrast withHypothesis 2. We furthermore find proof forHypothesis 4, or the relationship between the Herfindahl measure and standards consortium survival, meaning that an increase in competition in a standards consortia also increases the probability of standards consortia failure.

Through regression we test the presentedHypotheses 3a and 3b. We apply the mediation measure as proposed by Kornak[20]. We test for mediation between the dichotomous measure of membership continuity and number of memberships perfirm. Model 20 that helps calculate the mediation measures is presented inTable 7.

We find that 4.9% of the effect of membership continuity on standards consortium survival is explained by the number of standards consortium memberships perfirm. The regression coefficient becomes bigger (away from the null) when the mediator is added, this indicates

that there is a negative effect of the number of standards consortium memberships perfirm and membership continuity, which is in line withHypotheses 3a. However, the mediating effect found is consider-ably low and could be the result of more complex relationships between the concepts, which warrants us from drawing strong inferences. In addition, we nowfind a positive (linear) relationship between number of memberships perfirm and standards consortia survival at p < .10 in contrast with the uni- and multivariate analysis. Wefind that 23.3% of that relationship is explained by the dichotomous membership con-tinuity measure. This means it is not an autonomous relationship, but a result of the negative association between the occurrence of member-ship continuity and the number of membermember-ships perfirm, in line with

Hypothesis 3b.

5. Conclusion and discussion

In this paper we have studied the effects of commitment and internal standards consortium competition on standards consortium survival. The internal dynamics of standards consortia and the survival of standards consortia may play an important role in standardization, but have still been largely understudied phenomena in standardization and dominant design literature.

We had expected trust to be paramount in standardization efforts in high-tech industries and, as a consequence, that having a relatively closed group of collaborators benefits the outcome of consortium standardization. We have found, however, that the entrance of new members in standards consortia increases the longevity of these consortia, and that limiting openness for new members is detrimental to the survival of standards consortia. These findings suggest that standards consortia that keep their group of managing members too closed in their search for a uniform presence, or avoidance of scope creep may be doing so at the cost of premature disbandment. This may be especially true in markets with high uncertainties where learning effects together with flexibility in standardization are important factors for standards dominance[38]. Being open to new entrants seems to be a good strategy.

We expected an inverted u-shaped relationship between the num-ber of standards consortium memnum-berships per firm and standards consortium survival but we were unable to uncover any relationship. It is possible that certain standards consortia with shared members enhance each other through inter-organizational learning and informa-tion sharing and compete to a lesser degree for members’ resources than other standards consortia. Knowing how standards consortia are linked through cooperation and competition may therefore help determine whether concurrent standards consortium memberships are beneficial or detrimental to standards consortium survival.

Table 5

Correlation matrix of coefficients of extended Cox model.

1 2 3 4 5 1.βYearOfFoundation 1.000 2.βNumberOfMembershipsPerFirm −.1693 1.000 3.βMembershipContinuity −.0045 −.2732 1.000 4.βHerfindahlIndex .1482 .5308 −.3853 1.000 5.βMembershipContinuity(t) −.0286 .2480 −.9033 .2310 1.000 Table 6

Results of extended Cox regression.

18 19 main βMembershipContinuity −6.79754 (4.698873) βMembershipContinuityDichotomous 1.763105*** (.6385409) βHerfindahlIndex .0002026*** .0001643** (.0000759) (.0000709) tvc βMembershipContinuity(t) 3.481442** (1.60062) No. observations 409 409 No. Subjects 69 69

No. Failures (i.e. consortia terminations) 20 20 Log pseudolikelihood −66.12933 −65.53579 Prob > chi2 .0012 0.000

Variables in tvc equation interacted with time. Values for the variables are beta coefficients.

Values in parentheses are cluster-robust standard errors. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10

Table 7

Results of extended Cox regression.

20 main βNumberOfMembershipsPerFirm −.1258877* (.0675737) βMembershipContinuityDichotomous 1.960416*** (3.25) No. observations 409 No. Subjects 69

No. Failures (i.e. consortia terminations) 20 Log pseudolikelihood −65.29871

Prob > chi2 .0001

Variables in tvc equation interacted with time. Values for the variables are beta coefficients.

Values in parentheses are cluster-robust standard errors. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.10

X. Kamps et al. Computer Standards & Interfaces 52 (2017) 105–113

(10)

We have theorized a negative impact of internal standards con-sortium competition on standards concon-sortium survival. We indeedfind that standards consortia that have a higher competition in terms of the Herfindahl index do have a higher chance of disbandment. Concentration of total revenues at a limited number of parties within a standards consortium seems to lead to a bigger pursuit of standards consortia survival. Ahuja[1]finds that when it comes to formation of

interfirm linkages “commercial capital is a more highly valued currency for the averagefirm than is technical capital” (p. 334). Smaller firms may thus pursuit standards consortia survival as a means of having a bigger access to capital, whereas more establishedfirms may be willing to accommodate this in exchange of access to knowledge. Whereas such constellations may be less prone to opportunism, it may also lead to a futile pursuit of success in adverse market conditions.

We expected a positive effect of the degree of membership continuity within the standards consortium on standards consortium survival, but due to highly skewed data, we were only able to distinguish a relationship between a dichotomous measurement of membership continuity. Standards consortia that experience influx of new entrants have a higher probability of standards consortium survival than standards consortia in which memberships remain stable. New members in standards consortia may increase the scope of consortia, leading to increased exploration for best applications for their standards[41]. The effect of openness to new (strategic) members was important in the battle between HD-DVD and ray. The Blu-Ray Disc Association was a newly formed standards consortium, while the HD-DVD Promotion Group was an initiative of the DVD Forum already formed in 1995. Initially, the number of members in the Blu-ray Disc Association and the HD-DVD Promotion Group remained relatively constant, but increased sharply from mid-2003 to 2005[10]. With this increase in members, both standards consortia also became increasingly diverse in terms of the primary industry of their members

[41]. The number and diversity of the board directors for the Blu-ray Disc Association also increased greatly over the years, while the managing members for the HD-DVD Promotion group remained the same. This stability in managing members for the HD-DVD Promotion group may have stemmed from an inward-looking myopia. Van den Ende et al. [41] found that standards consortia that areflexible to change have more diversity in their networks, which increases the likelihood of standard success. Our findings indicate that similar dynamics may also exist at the highest organizational unit of standards consortia, as openness to new members increases the likelihood for standards consortia to survive. Another explanation of the positive relationship between membership continuity and consortium survival is that expected success of the consortium attracts new members. Combining these two cause effect relationships results in self-reinfor-cing dynamics: expected success attracts new members and these new members contribute to success, etc.

Lastly, as hypothesized, we found a negative relationship between the number of standards consortium memberships per firm and membership continuity. Furthermore, we found an indication of a positive relationship. Conversely, we have also found indication for our expected negative association between membership continuity and the number of memberships perfirm. It seems that standards consortia that have a higher degree of membership continuity lower their outside options. We were unable tofind a resulting autonomous relationship between the number of standards consortium memberships per firm and consortia survival.

In conclusion, we have introduced a novel way of looking at standards consortia and their dynamics. We expected that a more stable highest organizational unit of a standards consortium would be beneficial to the development of trust and the avoidance of scope creep, and therefore to standards consortium survival. We found, however that the openness to new members in the highest organizational unit of a standards consortium enhances its chances of survival. This is in line with previous research pointing to the importance of openness to new

stakeholders for the success of standards. In addition, we have found proof for the hypothesized negative relationship between standards consortium competition and standards consortium survival. This could be explained by the fact that standards consortia with asymmetrical distribution of power may lead to less opportunistic behaviour than those constellations characterized by more internal rivalry.

Our study has certain limitations that open the way for future research. Certain standards consortia benefit from being connected to other standards consortia through its members. Commitment as measured by the number of standards consortium memberships per firm in a consortium may trivialize the importance of such linkages and may explain the lack of effect found in this study. Future research should distinguish between competing, enhancing and unrelated standards consortia, because that may help assess the degree to which concurrent standards consortium memberships reflects technical-eco-nomic commitment.

Another limitation is that we had to rely on external sources of data to build our database. Membership data and consortia procedures about rotating leadership constellations are not always publically available, but we were largely able to overcome this limitation by extensive analysis of the data. Relationships between the members within standards consortia and across standards consortia are not always formal and publically available either, and therefore hard to measure. However, “these relations could play a prominent role in reaching a standard for complex systems” ([38], p.120). Determining such roles requires a different research methodology. Another limita-tion is that we focused on standards consortia with corporate member-ship. Other consortia, in particular in the ITfield, may have different rules for decision making. This might have implications for the results -another topic for future research.

The limited amount of standards consortia that experience the failure event (termination) in our database results from our conserva-tive approach of considering terminations as failures, which we believe is fruitful for making statistical inferences, but it limits us in the amount of (control) variables we could enter in this study in order not to violate the EPV rule of thumb. Apart from the methodological limitations, the sample size may also explain the lack of an effect found for certain concepts on standards consortium survival. A study with a larger sample size (also including standards organizations in other industry categories than IT, CE, TE, and HA) and more failures could replicate our research.

Future research could also assess more closely the unexpected effect of the influx of new members on standards consortium survival and possibly relate it to standards dominance. The standards consortia in our database were primarily standards promoting or standards pro-moting and developing consortia, making it impossible for us to distinguish between promoting and developing standards consortia. Future research may distinguish between the two, and possibly also between horizontal and vertical standards consortia.

In addition, we now focus on internal standards consortium competition in terms of commercial power. Future research could extend our research to more technological competition, as close technological rivals tend to avoid collaboration in order to gain competitive advantage.

Further research may also distinguish between different types of new member entrants that may be beneficial for standards consortium survival, and whether the entrance of new members is also a result of other characteristics of success of standards consortia. We believe that this study opens the door for such future research.

Appendix A. Supporting information

Supplementary data associated with this article can be found in the online version atdoi:10.1016/j.csi.2017.02.002.

X. Kamps et al. Computer Standards & Interfaces 52 (2017) 105–113

(11)

References

[1]G. Ahuja, The duality of collaboration: inducements and opportunities in the formation of interfirm linkages, Strateg. Manag. J. 21 (3) (2000) 317–343. [2]R.W. Axelrod, R. Mitchell, R. Thomas, D. Bennett, E. Bruderer, Coalition formation

in standard-setting alliances, Manag. Sci. 41 (9) (1995) 1493–1508.

[3]H.H. Basehart, The effect of membership stability on continuity and experience in U.S. State legislative committees, Legis. Stud. Q. 5 (1) (1980) 55–68.

[4] C.F. Cargill, Why standardization efforts fail, J. Electr. Publ. 14 (1) (2011) (Retrieved March 1, 2014, from)〈http://quod.lib.umich.edu/j/jep/3336451.0014. 103/–why-standardization-efforts-fail?rgn=main;view=fulltext〉.

[5]D. Calcei, Z. M'Chirgui, Coalition building dynamics in video format wars, Innov.: Manag. Policy Pract. 14 (3) (2012) 324–336.

[6]T.K. Das, N. Rahman, Determinants of partner opportunism in strategic alliances: a conceptual framework, J. Bus. Psychol. 25 (1) (2010) 55–74.

[7]T.K. Das, B. Teng, Instabilities of strategic alliances: an internal tensions perspective, Org. Sci. 11 (1) (2000) 77–101.

[8]H.J. De Vries, G.W. Hendrikse, The Dutch Banking Chipcard game - Understanding a battle between two standards, Int. Stud. Manag.Org. 31 (1) (2001) 106–125. [9]E. Den Hartigh, J.R. Ortt, G. Van, de Kaa, C.C.M. Stolwijk, Platform control during

battles for market dominance: the case of Apple versus IBM in the early personal computer industry, Technovation 48–49 (2016) 4–12.

[10] S. Den Uijl, H.J. De Vries, Pushing technological progress by strategic manoeuvr-ing: the triumph of Blu-ray over HD-DVD, Bus. Hist. 55 (8) (2013) 1361–1384. [11] G. Dokko, L. Rosenkopf, Social capital for hire? Mobility of technical professionals

andfirm influence in wireless standards committees, Org. Sci. 21 (3) (2010) 677–695.

[12] W. Evan, P. Olk, R & D consortia: a new U.S. organizational form, Sloan Manag. Rev. 31 (3) (1990) 37–46.

[13] T.F. González, M. Guillén, Organizational commitment: a proposal for a wider ethical conceptualization of‘normative commitment’, J. Bus. Eth. 78 (3) (2008) 401–414.

[14] H.R. Greve, H. Mitsuhashi, J.A.C. Baum, Greener pastures: outside options and strategic alliance withdrawal, Org. Sci. 24 (1) (2013) 79–98.

[15] G.T. Gundlach, R.S. Achrol, J.T. Mentzer, The structure of commitment in exchange, J. Mark. 59 (1) (1995) 78–92.

[16] L.C. Hamilton, Statistics with STATA: version12, Cengage Learning, Boston, 2013. [17] R. Hawkins, The rise of consortia in the information and communication

technology industries: emerging implications for policy, Telecommun. Policy 23 (2) (1999) 159–173.

[18] J. He, J.T. Mahoney, H.C. Wang, Firm capability, corporate governance and competitive behaviour: a multi-theoretic framework, Int. J. Strateg. Change Manag. 1 (4) (2009) 293–318.

[19] D.G. Kleinbaum, M. Klein, Survival Snalysis: A Self-learning Text, 2nd edition, Springer, New York, 2005.

[20] J. Kornak, Survival Analysis II. Lecture on Survival Analysis, department Epidemiology & Biostatistics, UCSF School of Medicine, 2013 University of California, San Francisco. Retrieved May 28, 2014〈http://rds.epiucsf.org/ticr/ syllabus/courses/8/2013/04/09/Lecture/notes/lectureS2.ppt〉.

[21] R. Lunnan, S.A. Haugland, Predicting and measuring alliance performance: a multidimensional analysis, Strateg. Manag. J. 29 (5) (2008) 545–556. [22] G. Maldonado, S. Greenland, Simulation study of confounder-selection strategies,

Am. J. Epidemiol. 138 (1993) 923–936.

[23] L.M. Markus, C.W. Steinfield, R.T. Wigand, Industry-wide information systems standardization as collective action: the case of the U.S. residential mortgage

industry, MIS Q. 30 (2006) 439–465.

[24] M. Mills, Introducing Survival and Event History Analysis., Sage, London, 2011. [25] P. Olk, C. Young, Why members stay in or leave an R & D consortium: performance

and conditions of membership as determinants of continuity, Strateg. Manag. J. 18 (11) (1997) 855–877.

[26] R.S. Rosenbloom, M.A. Cusumano, Technological pioneering and competitive advantage: the Birth of the VCR Industry, Calif. Manag. Rev. 29 (4) (1987) 51–76. [27] L. Rosenkopf, A. Metiu, V.P. George, From the bottom up? Technical Committee

activity and alliance formation, Adm. Sci. Q. 46 (4) (2001) 748–772. [28] O. Schilke, A. Goerzen, Alliance management capability: an investigation of the

construct and its measurements, J. Manag. 36 (5) (2010) 1192–1219. [29] C.A.J. Simons, H.J. de Vries, Standaard of Maatwerk: Bedrijfskeuzes Tussen

Uniformiteit en verscheidenheid, Academic Service, Schoonhoven, 2002. [30] R. Srinivasan, Sources, Characteristics and Effects of Emerging Technologies:

research Opportunities in Innovation, Ind. Mark. Manag. 37 (2008) 633–640. [31] R. Srinivasan, G.L. Lilien, A. Rangaswamy, The emergence of dominant designs, J.

Mark. 70 (2) (2006) 1–17.

[32] D.L. Streiner, Breaking up is hard to do: the heartbreak of dichotomizing continuous data, Can. J. Psychiatry 47 (3) (2002) 262–266.

[33] F.F. Suarez, J.M. Utterback, Dominant Designs and the Survival of Firms, Strateg. Manag. J.l 16 (6) (1995) 415–430.

[34] F.F. Suarez, Battles for technological dominance: an integrative framework, Res. Policy 33 (2) (2004) 271–286.

[36] G.W. Sun, T.L. Shook, G.L. Kay, Inappropriate use of bivariable analysis to screen risk factors for use in multivariable analysis, J. Clin. Epidemiol. 49 (1999) 907–916.

[38] G. Van de Kaa, Standards Battles for Complex Systems: empirical Research on the Home Network, Rotterdam School of Management, Erasmus University, Rotterdam, 2009.

[39] G. Van de Kaa, H.J. De Vries, J.C.M. Van den Ende, Strategies in network industries: the importance of inter-organisational networks, complementary goods, and commitment, Technol. Anal. Strateg. Manag. 27 (1) (2015) 73–86. [40] G. Van de Kaa, H. De Vries, Factors for winning format battles: a comparative case

study., Technol. Forecast. Social Change 91 (2) (2015) 222–235.

[41] J. Van den Ende, G. Van de Kaa, S. Den Uyl, H.J. De Vries, The paradox of standard flexibility: the effects of co-evolution between standard and interorganizational network, Org. Stud. 33 (5,6) (2012) 705–736.

[42] K.P. Vatcheva, M. Lee, J.B. McCormick, M.H. Rahbar, Multicollinearity in Regression Analyses Conducted in Epidemiologic Studies, 2016 (Sunnyvale, Calif), 6(2), 227.

[43] E. Vittinghoff, C.E. McCulloch, Relaxing the rule of ten events per variable in logistic and cox regression, Int. J. Epidemiol. 165 (6) (2007) 710–718. [44] M.B.H. Weiss, M. Sirbu, Technological choice in voluntary standards committees:

an empirical analysis, Econ. Innov. New Technol. 1 (1–2) (1990) 111–113. [48] M. Weiss, C. Cargill, Consortia in the standards development process, J. Am. Soc.

Inform. Sci. 43 (8) (1992) 559–565.

[45] R.A. Yaffee, M. McGee, An Introduction to Time Series Analysis and Forecasting: With Applications of SAS® and SPSS®, Academic Press, Inc, San Diego, 2000. [46] K. Zhao, S. Khan, M. Xia, Sustainability of vertical standards consortia as

communities of practice: a multilevel framework, Int. J. Electron. Commer. 16 (1) (2011) 11–40.

[47] A. Zaheer, G.G. Bell, Benefiting from network position: firm capabilities, structural holes, and performance, Strateg. Manag. J. 26 (9) (2005) 809–825.

[48] K. Zhao, M. Xia, M. Shaw, What motivatesfirms to contribute to consortium-based e-business standardization?, Int. J. Electron. Commer. 28 (2) (2011) 305–334. X. Kamps et al. Computer Standards & Interfaces 52 (2017) 105–113

Cytaty

Powiązane dokumenty

Związek Słowiański (Hufiec Wolnych Słowian), działający w latach 1945– –1948 na terenie Kalisza, Dąbrowy Górniczej i Gdyni, Konspiracyjny Związek Harcerstwa Polskiego

Wyprawa to dla nas egzotyczna, bo autorka recenzowanego studium odkrywa przed nami nie zbadany, jak dotąd, świat krystalizowania się i krzepnięcia idei polskiego modernizmu

The NMEA standard gets user access to such information as his geographic position on Earth, speed and acceleration of moving, angle of elevation, number of

PROCEEDINGS OF THE ETHICOMP* 2020 18th International Conference on the Ethical and Social Impacts of ICT Logroño, La Rioja, Spain June 15 – July 6 online.. Title Paradigm Shifts in

Om data zo breed te kunnen gebruiken, werkt DiTTlab aan nieuwe simulatiemodellen die kunnen omgaan met meer modaliteiten (waaronder automatisch rijden) en meer aspecten (bijvoorbeeld

Syrach dwukrotnie wzywa ucznia, aby nie brał na swe ramiona tego, co jest cięższe od jego możliwości, co przerasta jego siły (por. Szukanie mądrości, jak zapewnił autor w

Pierw szy pełny przekład Pana Tadeusza na język białoruski, doko­ nany w polskich więzieniach przez Bronisława Taraszkiewicza — obroń­ cę praw wolnościowych

In this paper, we describe two approaches to quantify the rela- tion between rule violations and actual faults, and present empirical data on this relation for the MISRA C 2004