• Nie Znaleziono Wyników

Macroeconomic Effects of the Integration with the EU: VAT in Agriculture

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Macroeconomic Effects of the Integration with the EU: VAT in Agriculture"

Copied!
13
0
0

Pełen tekst

(1)

A C T A U N I V E R S I T A T I S L O D Z I E N S I S __________ FOLIA OECONOMICA 182, 2004

Justyna W iktorow icz*

MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE INTEGRATION WITH

THE EU: VAT IN AGRICULTURE

1. In trod u ction

As far as taxation is concerned, including value added tax, agriculture has always been treated in a slightly different way com pared to o ther sectors. Special VAT treatm ent was due to high collection and adm inistration costs in agriculture. M oreover seasonal output and tim e discrepancy betw een outlay and output m akes m easurem ent and paym ent procedures even m ore com plicated. A nother reason behind this solution is regressivity o f VAT.

Yet econom ic theory would suggest that agricultural products should be subject to V A T (Ebrill at al. 2001, p. 102). H ow ever in transition period high collection costs may dim inish benefits stem m ing from this approach. A com prom ise is exem ption o f agricultural products from VA T. T hen farm ers are not subject to tax adm inistration when reduced V A T rate enables them to recover at least part o f tax charged in inputs.

T he aim o f this article is to show econom ic effects o f V A T in agriculture. A variety o f approaches em ployed by different E U m em ber states and Poland will enable us to pursue a sim ulation analysis o f effects o f the flat rate and the norm al tax schem es. Then we will prove that V A T exerts an influence on area and production concentration in Polish agriculture.

2. VAT in the European and Polish agriculture

In the EU regulations concerning value added tax are provided for in the 6 U) C ouncil D irective o f 17 M ay I9 7 7 1 w hereas in Poland in A c t o f 8 Ja nu ary 1993

PhD., Chair o f Econom ic and Social Statistics, University o f Łódź.

1 C ouncil Directive 388/77/E E C on the harmonisation o f the laws o f the M ember States relating to turnover tax - C om m on system o f value added tax: uniform basis o f assessm ent ( OJ L N o 145 o f 13.06.1977).

(2)

on goods and service tax and excise2 and especially the am endm ent o f 20 July

2000 that cam e into force on 4 lh Septem ber 2000.

T he 6th D irective provides for a com m on schem e for farm ers in relation to agricultural undertakings. The directive does not give a definition o f this term , instead, it provides for som e features that legislators in M em ber States should consider. A ccording to these guidelines, agricultural activity involves 5 fields o f production: crop production, stock farming, forestry, fisheries and processing of products deriving essentially from own agricultural production, (the last activity is not classified as agricultural production activity in Polish legislation and thus is not subject to “agricultural” VAT, in Poland only unprocessed goods can be regarded as agricultural products). The 6lh D irective provides for list o f services that are also subject to com m on flat rate schem e (this has not been applied in Polish legislation).

V A T in ag ricu ltu re both in the EU and Poland is ap plied in tw ofold schem e. Som e ag ricultural producers apply the norm al value added tax schem e, w hereas others prefer the flat rate schem e ( F lat Rate C om pensation in the EU, f l a t rate refu n d system in P oland) which is su pp lem entary to general V A T taxatio n schem e both in the EU and in Poland. Its rules are laid dow n in article 25 o f the 6 lh C ouncil D irective and article 7 o f the P olish Act that m ake up for the basis o f the flat rate schem e for farm ers in the EU and Poland, respectively.

2.1. The VAT flat rate scheme and its impact

T he sim plified flat-rate schem e for farm ers is based on tw o guidelines: 1) establishing tax rules that would apply to som e farm ers w here the application o f the norm al value added tax would give rise to difficulties;

2) granting farm ers a partial V A T refund o f tax charged on purchases o f agricultural inputs like agricultural m achinery, fodder, fertilizers, fuel etc.

A pplication o f the sim plified flat rate schem e is not obligatory. The European C om m ission left it to individual M em ber States to decide what taxation system they w ish to apply for the agricultural sector. If a M em ber State would choose the flat rate schem e it is required to give farm ers subject to the flat rate schem e a possibility to choose between this schem e and the norm al VAT schem e. T he EU legislation also provides for a possibility for a M em ber State to apply exem ption from the flat rate schem e for certain categories o f farm ers. It applies especially to those producers that conduct a w ide range o f activities and

1 A ct o f 8 January 1993 on g o o d s a n d service tax a n d excise [D z. U. 1993, N o 11, item 50 with further amendments].

(3)

can be treated on equal term s as other VAT taxpayers. T he flat rate schem e js not applied in D enm ark, Finland, Portugal and Sweden.

Flat rate com pensation is a direct effect o f excluding flat rate farm ers from the possibility to deduct input VAT. The flat rate com pensation is supposed to com pensate for V A T charged on inputs, but the refund level should be balanced so as the refund does not exceed the paid VAT. In order to ensure that the EU legislation provides for the method to calculate flat rate com pensation percentages on the basis o f m acroeconom ic statistics supplied by flat rate farmers. A dditional protection against overestim ated refund is a m echanism o f relative com pensation.

M em ber States may provide for com pensation to the farm er to be paid (K iszka 2000):

> By the purchaser o f agricultural products or services. In this case the taxable person to whom a flat rate farm er supplied products or services is obliged to add to purchase price the am ount o f flat rate com pensation and then he can deduct the com pensation as input tax from his output tax. In Poland the solution is sim ilar;

> Indirectly, by the public authorities. This model is applied for exam ple

when a flat rate farm er delivers goods or services to public sector and firm s not liable to tax. A given M em ber State decides upon a com pensation m ethod to be applied in this case.

The flat rate V A T com pensation seem s to be a good solution for farm ers, especially for small farm owners. A ccording to the studies carried out in the EU, application o f this schem e in practice raises some d ifficulties and the most im portant are (Ebrill at al. 2001, p. 103):

1 )T h e flat rate does not correspond exactly to farm ers’ expenditures on inputs. Studies conducted in Spain in the 80s showed that depending on type o f production V A T charged on inputs was approxim ately from 1.1% (for olives) to 5.7% (for gardening).

2) Som e M em ber States give all farm ers, regardless their output volum e, the possibility to choose betw een flat rates. If a flat rate is low a lot o f big farm ers prefer the norm al tax schem e since the flat rate schem e does not allow for recovery o f V A T charged on inputs. But if flat rate com pensation percentage is high farm ers can choose the flat rate schem e, though the C om m ission recom m ends it for small farms.

3) T he p roblem to fix the flat rate is w hether to include d irec t ag riculture export or not. Inclusion o f export results in increase o f final prices abroad w hat m eans w orse co m p etitiv en ess o f agricultural products. E x clu d in g export, on the o th er hand, reduces export since farm ers keep low er prices on dom estic m arket and by doing so they do not get com pensation for V A T charged in

(4)

capital goods. H ence the C om m ission suggests that direct ex po rt be subject to com pensatio n and purchasers in foreign m arkets should have the p o ssibility o f V A T refund.

4) T he status o f the flat rate tax is not fully defined. On one hand, the flat rate is not a typical V A T rate, but it is treated as tax d ed uctio n from inputs from those w ho pu rch ase products from farm ers. As a result co m pen satio n is fixed for “average farm er” , regardless o f harvest and o ther unpred ictable factors.

T o sum up, in the light o f the 6lh Directive flat rate farm ers can benefit from exem ption from liability to calculate and pay taxes on their agricultural products and services and from lack o f flat rate com pensation for input VAT. Exem ption from tax liability entails further benefits and so flat rate farm ers do not have to register for V A T and keep books.

2.2. VAT rates in agriculture

V A T system for agriculture differs betw een M em ber States. T he tax is sim ilar in its form, but there are clear differences when we look in detail. O ne of m ajor differences is rate levels and their num ber. T he products in given rate ranges are also different. A m ong EU countries only Sw eden and D enm ark have the sam e 25% V A T rate on all products and services.

A lthough the 6th D irective clearly states that reduced rate can no t be low er than 5% and zero-rated V A T can be applied only for exp ort, som e M em ber S tates do not m eet these requirem ents. Z ero-rated V A T for m ajority of ag ricu ltural p ro ducts is used in Ireland and U nited K ingdom (it concerns farm ers su b ject to the norm al tax schem e, flat rate co m p en satio n p ercentage for flat rate farm ers is establish ed on the level o f 4% in G reat B ritain and 4.2% in Ireland). S im ilarly in Portugal reduced rates are app lied in ag ricu ltu re i.e. 5% for fresh fruit and vegetables, honey, table w ine, 12% for dried fruit and flow ers and zero rate for the rest o f products (but farm ers do not have an option to ch oose the flat rate schem e for V A T). In som e m em ber states, d espite d irective re com m endations, product exem ptions are ap p lied fo r certain groups o f p roducts (e.g. anim al produce in F rance, unprocessed goods in S pain) as well as pro d u cer exem ptions (e.g. certain groups o f p ro d u cers in F rance). D etailed inform ation on V A T rates in EU co untries and in Poland is depicted in T ab. 1.

(5)

Table 1. V A T rates for agricultural products in the EU and in Poland in 20 0 0 V A T rate Country Standard

rate G oods normal

schem e flat rate schem e

Austria 2 0 .0 M ost products 10.0 10.0

B elgium 2 1 .0 M ost products 6.0 6.0

Denmark 2 5 .0 A ll products 2 5 .0 _

Finland 2 2 .0 All products 17.0 _

France 20.6" M ost vegetable products W ine

5.5 2 0 .6

3.05

All livestock products except animals for meat Anim als for meat

- 3.05 4.0 Products sold through a producers’ group:

Fruit, vegetables, wine 3.05

Pigs, eggs and poultry4.0

Greece 22.0 M ost products 8.0 8.0

W ine, cotton, raw tobacco, w ool and raw hides 18.0 18.0 16.0 Products used for human and animal feed, other

Spain than wine

All products not used for human and animal

7.0 4.5

consum ption, wine

All unprocessed products, except those from independent breeders

16.0 4.5

4.5

Netherlands 17.5 M ost products 6.0 5.93

Tree nursery products 17.5 5.93

Ireland 2 1 .0 Horses, live cattle, sheep, pigs, goats 4.2 4.2

Other agricultural products 0 .0 4.2

Luxembourg 15.0 M ost products and services 8.0 8.0

Germany 16.0 M ost products 7.0 9.0

Portugal

17.0 Fresh vegetables and fruit, honey, regular table

wine 5.0

Dried fruit, flowers 12.0 _

Other agricultural products 0.0 _

Sweden 2 5 .0 All products 2 5 .0 _

United 17.5 Products generally used for human and animal

Kingdom

consum ption (including seeds, seedlin gs and

animals) 0.0 4.0

Other products and services 17.5 4.0

Italy

2 0 .0 M ost plant products, oilseed s, olive oil, butter,

cheese 4 .0 4.0

E ggs, raw milk 10.0 9.0

Cattle 10.0 7.0

Pigs

All other products

10.0 20 .0

7.5 4.0 Poland 2 2 .0 U nprocessed agricultural products 3.0 3.0

“ N ow 19,6%.

(6)

Table 2. V A T for agricultural inputs in the EU countries in 2 0 0 0

Country Inputs V A T rate

(%) !

I 2 3

Austria D iesel fuel for heating, gas, electricity 20.0 Animal feedingstuffs, fertilizers, water 10.0

Purchase and tenancy o f land 0.0

Belgium Purchase and tenancy o f land

Animal feedingstuffs, seeds, fertilizers, agricultural services, veterinary О

services 6.0

Coal (solid fuel)

Construction and maintenance o f farm buildings, farm equipment.

12.0

pesticides, fu e l, gas, electricity 21.,0

Denmark Purchase o f land and buildings 0 , 0

A ll products 25.0

Finland M ost products 22.0

Animal feedingstuffs 17.0

France(/’) N on-processed agricultural products (including breeding stock), work

under contract (")

Fertilizers, animal feedingstuffs, pesticides 5.5 Construction and maintenance o f farm buildings, most services 20.6

Petroleum products 2 0 .6 0

Greece Purchase and tenancy o f land, manual workers’ wages, insurance

premiums О

Seed animal feedingstuffs, breeding stock, fertilizers, pesticides M ost farm equipment, repair and maintenance o f machinery, motor fuels,

8.0

Installations and buildings, electricity, lubricants, LPG, wire fencing 18.0

Spain Purchase and tenancy o f land О

Inputs o f agricultural origin, pharmaceuticals, most services 7.0

Inputs o f industrial origin 16.0

Netherlands Indemnity insurance, purchase, renting and tenancy o f im m ovable property

Seeds, fertilizers, fuel for heating, feedingstuffs, breeding stock, som e

(u) services, pesticides, pharmaceuticals, work under contract, equipment

T elecom m unications, veterinary services, fuels, agricultural equipment and accessories maintenance and repair o f farm buildings, transport

6.0

services, electricity 17.5

Ireland Feedingstuffs, fertilizers (10 kg and more), cereals, beet, hay, cake etc., seeds and propagating material, veterinary products for oral

administration

Concrete and blocks o f concrete, electricity, solid fuels, oil for heating, 0.0 gas diesel fuel for tractors, most services, machine repair

Fertilizers (less than 10 kg), pesticides, disinfectants and detergents, veterinary products for injection and veterinary equipment, farm equipment including tractors, building materials, second-hand goods,

12.5

(7)

1 2 3 Luxemburg Lease, hire and transfer o f m ovable property

Inputs: seeds and propagating material, livestock and livestock products, feedingstuffs, fertilizers, pesticides, pharmaceuticals,

O i

agricultural services 3.0

Gas and electricity 6 .0

Veterinary services, solid fuels, mineral oils

Farm machinery and equipment, construction and maintenance o f farm

12.0

buildings motor fuels, som e services (e.g. transport) 15.0

Germany Purchase o f land (")

Inputs o f agricultural origin (feedingstuffs, seeds etc.)

Inputs o f industrial origin (fertilizers, pesticides, electricity and fuel, buildings and machinery, building materials and accessories)

7 .0

Non-agricultural services 16.0

Portugal Fertilizers and pesticides, animal feedingstuffs, seeds, live animals, machinery, equipment and tractors

Electricity, fuels and gas 5.0

M aintenance and repair o f machinery, petrol, coal 17.0

Sw eden All products and services 25 .0

United Interest relief grants on purchase and renting o f land, insurance. Г~ ---Kingdom financial costs

M ost products generally used for human and animal consum ption.

о water

Pow er fuels (except road diesel fuel, petrol), dom estic electricity,

0.0 electricity

Petrol, lubricants, road diesel fuel, fertilizers, chem icals, agricultural

5.0

machinery 17.5

Italy Agricultural loans, rural leases О

Animal feedingstuffs o f vegetable origin 2.0

Work under contract 10.0

Fertilizers

Animal feedingstuffs o f animal origin, seeds, breeding stock, pesticides, products o f mineral and chemical origin, additives for animal feed,

4.0

fuels, lubricants, pharmaceuticals

M achinery and equipment, gas and electricity, building materials, most

10.0

services 20 .0

,a> exempt; lb> refunded; (<> deductible VA T if the product is used on ly for agricultural purposes.

S o u r с e: A s same as Tab. 1.

Likew ise agricultural products, rates for agricultural inputs vary betw een M em ber States (detailed inform ation is given in Tab. 2). In m ajority o f m em ber states rates are differentiated in a follow ing way:

1) Typical inputs (except m achinery and agricultural equipm ent) are subject to reduced rate, that is usually equal the rate for unprocessed goods, and other goods and services are subject to standard rate (France).

(8)

2) Inputs o f agricultural origin (animal feedingstuffs, seeds etc.) are subject to reduced rate (as the rate for unprocessed agricultural products) and inputs o f industrial origin (pesticides, fertilizers, m achinery) are subject to standard rate (e.g. Spain, G erm any).

3) All inputs typical for agricultural production (including m achinery and equipm ent), as well as electricity, fuels (except petrol) are subject to reduced rate (e.g. Portugal).

4) D iverse reduced rates are applied for different groups o f inputs and standard rate is applied for products o f general use like petrol (e.g. Luxem burg, Italy).

5) Zero rated V A T is applied for inputs o f agricultural origin, reduced rate for inputs o f industrial origin (e.g. pesticides) and standard rate for other goods and services (U nited K ingdom and Ireland).

6) Flat rate V A T for all (D enm ark) or som e inputs for agricultural production (Finland, w here reduced rate is applied to anim al feedingstuffs).

7) Purchase or tenancy o f agricultural land is usually exem pt from V A T or subject to zero-rate.

3. T h e flat rate or n orm al tax schem e: sim u lation an a ly sis

As it has been m entioned individual M em ber States can introduce the Hat rate V A T schem e. It is not obligatory, though. N either are farm ers determ ined to choose a given option. T he analysis below show s financial effects o f such a solution (on m acroeconom ic scale and per 100 ha o f arable land) in M em ber States and in Poland. H ow ever these are only estim ations calculated on the basis o f data published by Eurostat and the Polish C entral Statistical O ffice (GU S) that cover agricultural output value, agricultural costs and their structure as well as V A T rates given in table 1 and 2.

The analysis is based on a purely technical assum ption that all farm s are hom ogeneous. It gives a possibility to analyse effects o f choice betw een the norm al tax schem e and the flat rate scheme. T his is only a sim ulation and we assum e that all farm s are liable to VAT follow ing either only norm al tax schem e or flat rate schem e, w hich in reality is not the case.

Table 3 clearly show s that the norm al V A T schem e is m ore beneficial from the point o f view o f the public budget. In m ajority i.e. 12 M em ber States the difference betw een output and input V A T is positive and this am ount would go to the public budget provided all farm ers are subject to the norm al tax scheme. For the w hole EU this am ount would account for m ore than 3 billion EU R , Italy and Spain contributing the biggest V A T revenues to the E U budget due to considerably low production costs and consequently low value o f input VAT.

(9)

T hese tw o countries have the biggest num ber o f farm s in the EU (2.3 m illion farm s in Italy and 1.2 million farms in Spain), but average VAT transferred to the EU budget by a statistical farm in both countries is not the highest in the EU. The biggest contribution is m ade by D enm ark and Sweden, countries with the sam e VAT rate on all products and services w hat m oreover is the highest V A T rate in EU (25% ).

Table 3. Theoretical V A T balance in the agricultural sector o f Member States and Poland in 2000. Sim ulation analysis based on assumption that all farmers follow normal tax schem e

The normal tax schem e

Output V A T Input VA T V A T balance (M io EUR) (M io EUR) (output V A T - input V A T )

Country total (M io EUR) per 100 ha UAA" (M io EUR) total (M io EUR) per 100 ha UAA (M io EUR) total (M io EUR) per 100 ha UA A (M io EUR) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Austria 4 3 6 .5 0 1.28 348.31 1.02 88.19 0 .2 6 Belgium 3 9 0 .3 0 2 .8 0 362.14 2.59 28.16 0 .2 0 Denmark 1603.90 6.02 959.52 3.60 644.38 2.42 Finland 51 4 .3 0 2.33 424.71 1.92 8 9.59 0.41 F ranee 2864.80 0.96 3058.93 1.02 -194.13 -0.07 Greece 9 0 5 .1 0 2.32 289.34 0.74 61 5 .7 6 1.58 Spain 2 2 1 8 .2 0 0.87 990.55 0.39 1227.65 0.48 Holland 1004.70 5.08 98 7 .3 7 5.00 17.33 0.09 Ireland 29.70 0.07 302.48 0.68 -272.78 -0.62 Luxemburg 19.10 1.41 7.92 0.59 11.18 0.83 Germany 2 7 6 5 .2 0 1.62 2463.88 1.44 30 1 .3 2 0.18 Portugal 76.90 0.20 191.30 0.49 -114.40 -0.29 Sweden 9 7 0 .9 0 3.26 690.46 2.32 28 0 .4 4 0.94 United Kingdom 76.40 0.05 1389.72 0.88 -1313.32 -0.84 Italy 31 9 4 .3 0 2.07 997.61 0.65 2 1 9 6 .6 9 1.43 EU 17070.30 1.31 13464.22 1.03 3606 .0 8 0.28 Poland b 2 1 0 .6 0.11 181.6 0.1 0 29 .0 0.01

“ U A A - U tilised Agricultural Area.

h Data for Poland (sim ulations) calculated for the exchange rate 1 EURO = 4 PLN.

Comment In bold letters are countries that find a given tax schem e more beneficial for farmers.

S o u r c e : ow n calculations on the basis o f Eurostat (http://w w w .europa.eu.int) and the Polish Central Statistical O ffice (G U S).

Since the average farm area in the EU is between 4.3 ha in G reece and 69.3 ha in Great Britain such an analysis is not precise. Therefore the estim ated am ounts were given per 100 ha o f UAA. And this approach shows that the biggest

(10)

contribution to the EU budget is made by Danish farm ers whereas the lowest by the Dutch. For public finances the normal tax scheme for VAT does not bring about desirable revenues in those countries that apply zero rated V A T for most agricultural products (Great Britain, Ireland), for some group o f products (Portugal) or if som e products are exempted from taxation (France).

Table 4. Theoretical V A T balance in the agricultural sector o f member states and Poland in 20 0 0 Sim ulation analysis based on the assumption that all farmers fo llo w the flat rate schem e

Flat rate scheme

V A T received by farmers Input VAT V A T refunded

Country (M io EUR) (M io EUR) (M io EUR)

total Per 100 ha UAA" total Per 100 ha UAA total Per 100 ha UAA A u stria 436.50 2.80 348.31 2.59 88.19 0.20 Belgium 390.30 2.21 362.14 1.76 28.16 0.45 France 1747.10 0.69 3058.93 1.20 - 1 3 1 1 . 8 3 -0 .5 2 G reece 905.10 0.53 289.34 0.17 615.76 0.36 Spain 1414.80 3.63 990.55 2.54 424.25 1.09 • N eth erla n d s 993.70 73.61 987.37 73.14 6.33 0.47 Ireland 2 2 3 .1 0 0.07 302.48 0.10 -7 9 .3 8 -0 .0 3 L u x em b o u rg 19.10 0.01 7.92 0.01 11.18 0.01 Germany 3565.50 13.37 2463.88 9.24 1101.62 4.13 United Kingdom 88 0 .9 0 2.59 1389.72 4.09 - 5 0 8 .8 2 - 1 .5 0 Italy 2219.60 5.02 997.61 2.26 1221.99 2.77 EU 12795.70 1.08 13464.22 0.94 1597.46 0. 13 Poland(h) 210.6 0.11 181.6 0.10 29.0 0.1

Com m ents as in Tab. 3. S o u r c e : A s same as Tab. 3.

The flat rate schem e contributes to higher budget revenues then the norm al tax schem e in U nited K ingdom , Ireland or France (see table 4), because in those countries a low flat rate com pensation percentage (4% , 4.2% and 3.05 or 4% respectively) does not com pensate for the V A T charged on inputs. As for a single farm , farm ers from Luxem burg generate biggest profits due to the fact that in L uxem burg V A T rate for basic agricultural inputs is low er than flat rate com pensation percentage (3% and 8% respectively). G erm any and Italy pay the highest am ounts o f flat rate com pensation percentages if calculated per 100 ha UAA.

The analysis o f Polish situation would suggest that the flat rate schem e would be more beneficial for farmers. N evertheless we need to bear in mind that V A T was introduced in Poland in 2000 and so pro-investm ent incentives have not been form ed yet (additionally we have bad situation in econom y and the sector) that would rise the value of input VAT.

(11)

4. V A T im p act on a g ricu ltu ral activity in Poland

As it has already been said, the idea behind V A T im position on agricultural products is to com pensate farm ers, at least partially, for tax charged on inputs. In Poland V A T on agricultural products was established three years ago and thus its im pact is not to be seen yet. W e shall expect V A T to increase incom e of farms and constitute pro-investm ent incentive in the sector. H ow ever, this refers m ainly to large, specialised farm s whereas econom ically weak farm s will gradually be liquidated. Therefore the total num ber o f farm s m ay decrease but the average agricultural farm would increase. T hus a long-term effect o f V A T in agriculture in Poland may be farming area concentration and concentration o f agricultural production.

It is interesting to identify all these effects, but on the other hand it is not easy because V A T has been in force for a short time. In this article we will attem pt to answ er the questions put forw ard in the introduction with the use o f regression methods.

R egression equations are formed on the basis o f a sam ple for Poland for years 1989-2001 (annual data). In order to show the im pact o f V A T on agricultural products; a V A T variable was introduced to the equations. This is a 0 -1 variable w here 1 is applied for years 2000-2001 and 0 for other years.

On the basis o f data published by the Polish C entral Statistical O ffice (G U S) the follow ing equations w ere form ed with the use o f the classical L east Squares M ethod: N = 2193,1 - 113,7749 V A T - 3,4060 QM t(at ) (80,99) (-3 ,3 1 8 ) (-4 ,8 2 2 ) R2 = 0 ,880037; D W =2,4833 ( 1) PPG = 8,531 + 0,6858 VAT,_t + 0,04864 t(a ,) (61,47) (4,600) (3,492) R 2 = 0,833382; D W =2,3569 (

2

)

K Q Z = -4 ,6 6 3 + 2,3107 VAT,_i + 7,7065 AV/VW,., +1,5046 A7,_i (3)

t(a ,) (-4 ,4 2 2 6 ) (2,194) (3,424) (5,075)

R 2 = 0,967648; D W = 2,0513

K Q R = -2 ,8 3 8 + 2,9038 VA T,_x + 4,5495 KINW,^ + 1,3089 (4)

t(a ,) (-2 ,2 2 3 ) (2,382) (1,747) (3,815)

(12)

where: N - num ber o f farms (thous.)

Q - gross agriculture output (thous. zl)

/ - gross nom inal disposable incom e in agriculture (thous. zl)

K l - gross nom inal disposable incom e per farm (thous. zl)

IN W - investm ent outlays in agriculture (thous. zl) K IN W - investm ent outlays per farm (thous. zl) PPG - average farm area (ha)

KQR - concentration o f crop production (gross crop output per farm in

thous. zl)

K Q Z - concentration o f animal production (gross anim al output per farm in thous. zl)

As equations (1) - (4) suggest V A T on unprocessed agricultural products exerts an im pact on farm area concentration, but its influence is deleted. The establishm ent o f V A T resulted in reduction o f num ber o f farm s by 114 thousand while average farm area increased by 0.7 ha. V A T can im pact on production concentration too. As its result anim al production (per farm ) increases by 2 thous. zl (per year) and crop production by about 3 thous.

5. C o n clu sio n s

1. D espite recom m endations o f the European C om m ission som e M em ber States apply V A T rate below 5% on agricultural products and agricultural inputs (even 0% in G reat B ritain and Ireland). M oreover som e countries (e.g. Spain, Belgium , France) apply exem ptions for som e goods o r groups o f producers.

2. V A T contributions to budgets are low er in countries with intensive agricultural production like Holland.

3. The flat rate schem e is more beneficial for an average farm er if the flat rate is high (e.g. G erm any, B elgium ) or if flat rate for agricultural products is considerably higher that the rate for basic inputs (e.g. Luxem burg).

4. V A T influences on farm area and production concentration in agriculture, but this im pact is deleted (at least one year).

R eferen ces

C ouncil Directive 388/77/E E C on the harmonisation o f the laws o f the Member States relating to turnover tax - C om m on system o f value added tax: uniform basis o f assessm ent ( OJ L No

(13)

Council Directive 92/77/E E C o f 19 October 1992 supplem enting the com m on system o f value added tax and amending Directive 77/388/E E C (approximation o f V A T rates) Official Journal L 3 1 6 , 3 1 /10/1992.

Council Directive o f 16 D ecem ber 1991 supplementing the com m on system o f value added tax and amending D irective 77/388/E E C with a view to the abolition o f fiscal frontiers Official Journal L 2 7 2 , 17/09/1992.

8"' C ouncil Directive o f 16 D ecem ber 1979 on the harmonisation o f the laws o f the M ember States relating to turnover tax - laws on value added tax reimbursement to taxable persons not established in a Member State (OJ L N o 331 o f 27.1 2 .1 9 7 9 ).

The 13"' C ouncil Directive o f 17 Novem ber 1986 on the harmonisation o f the laws o f the Member States relating to turnover tax - laws on value added tax reimbursement to taxable persons not established in the EU ( OJ L N o 3 2 6 o f 21. 11. 1986) .

E b r i I I L., K e e n M., B o d i n J.-P., S u m m e r s V. (2 0 0 1 ), The M o d em VAT, International M onetary Found, W ashington.

K i s z k a J. (2 0 0 0 ), O podatkow an ie ro ln ictw a pod a tk iem o d w a rto śc i d o d a n e j, „Prawo Unii Europejskiej”, nr 5.

P o l a k o w s k i D. (2 0 0 0 ), VA1 o d pro d u k tó w rolnych i n isk o p rzetw o rzo n ej żyw n ości w p ro w a d zo n y o d 4 .0 9 .2 0 0 0 r., Expert. W ydaw nictw o i Doradztwo, Wrocław.

R oczniki S tatystyczn e G U S 1 9 9 0 -2 0 0 2 .

Га i t A. A. (1 9 8 8 ), Value A d d ed Tax. International P ractice a n d P roblem s, International Monetary Found, W ashington D.C.

T o m c z y k S. (2 0 0 0 ). VAT w rolnictw ie, D ifin, Warszawa.

A ct o f 8 Janu ary 1993 on g o o d s a n d service tax a n d excise (D z. U. 1993, N o 11, item 50 with further amendments).

Z u b r z y c k i J. (2 0 0 0 ), VAT w rolnictw ie, „Przegląd Podatkow y”, nr 9 cz. I i nr 10 cz. 2. http://ww w.europa.eu.int

http://ww w.stat.gov.pl

J u s ty n a W ik to r o w ic z

M A K R O E K O N O M IC Z N E K O N S E K W E N C JE IN T E R G R A C JI PO LSK I Z UE NA PR Z Y K Ł A D Z IE PO D A TK U VAT W R O L N IC T W IE

Podatek V A T należy do najważniejszych konstrukcji podatkow ych. Pew ne dziedziny życia gospodarczego są przy tym objęte specjalnymi rozwiązaniami w tym zakresie. D o obszarów takich należy rolnictw o, które z uwagi na sw ą specyfikę objęte jest tzw. system em zryczałtow anego zwrotu podatku, który um ożliw ia drobnym producentom rolnym rozliczanie się z tej daniny na uproszczonych zasadach. R ozw iązanie takie stosow ane je st w w iększości krajów UE, jednak zw ykle na n ieco odm iennych zasadach. R óżnice tkw ią g łów n ie w w ysok ości staw ek V A T na nieprzetworzone produkty rolne oraz środki produkcji typow e dla rolnictwa, ale także w sposobie je g o administracji. Pow oduje to, że je g o efektyw ność jest zróżnicow ana w obrębie Piętnastki. W P olsce podatek V A T funkcjonuje w rolnictwie od niedawna, bo od w rześnia 2 0 0 0 r., przez co je g o konsekw encje ekonom iczne nie są je szc z e zbyt wyraźne. Jak wykazały przeprowadzone badania em piryczne, m oże on jednak stanowić jeden z istotnych czyn ników koncentracji obszarowej gospodarstw. M oże zatem korzystnie w pływ ać na przemiany agrarne w P olsce.

Cytaty

Powiązane dokumenty

This study examined the validity of the RIRP from the nonlinear point of view and its findings provide robust empirical evidence supporting the validity of the long-run

This work, through a statistical study of the effects of fiscal pol- icy of the European Union Member States in the area of consumption taxes, constitutes a research contribu- tion

Mając do us ze regowania według własnego stopnia ważności , czego n ajba rd z i ej obawiają się po wstąpieniu Polski do UE, zdecydowana większość rolników (72%)

For functions of one and two real variables, the rate of pointwise and uniform convergence of some Bernstein type algebraic polynomials is investigated..

by Stuart Pearson on 06/10/19. Re-use and distribution is strictly not permitted, except for Open Access articles... waves and currents needs to be better understood. A key factor

Although the theoretical basis of the sheltering effect still remains unsolved, the presently obtained results will be of practical use for the hull form design with least

1 - The standardized accelerated wear test: by wearing a group of nozzles until they reach 10% increase in flow rate of their nominal flow rate (specified by the

- The ultimate value of point resistance and sleeve friction of the model pile is independent of loading rate, so: No loading rate effects are found. - The stiffness of the soil