• Nie Znaleziono Wyników

Price patterns in an oligopoly with switching cost and uncertain demand

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Price patterns in an oligopoly with switching cost and uncertain demand"

Copied!
19
0
0

Pełen tekst

(1)

No. 3 2013 DOI: 10.5277/ord130306

Mateusz ZAWISZA* Bogumił KAMIŃSKI*

PRICE PATTERNS IN AN OLIGOPOLY

WITH SWITCHING COST AND UNCERTAIN DEMAND

Characteristics of price patterns have been investigated in an oligopoly market with costs for switching a provider. Two regimes of a company’s access to information have been considered. In the benchmark scenario, firms make decisions based on perfect information about demand. In the other – more realistic scenario – they conduct market research to estimate an unknown demand curve and therefore face uncertainty regarding their profit function, which in turn leads to suboptimal decision making. The authors inspected how a company’s access to information on demand, costs for switch-ing a provider and the rate of market renewal influence price patterns on the market. It has been shown that positive switching cost is a sufficient condition for price dispersion, as well as imperfect information about the company's profit function, e.g. from market research. The average price under the perfect information regime is lower than under market research based price setting, a higher switching cost makes it easier for companies to coordinate their prices and a higher rate of market re-newal softens the influence of the switching cost on market price.

Keywords: price competition, switching cost, agent-based modeling, uncertain demand, price volatility

1. Introduction

Oligopoly markets are often characterized by repeated purchasing. For instance: the renewal of a contract with a mobile operator or Internet service provider, purchas-ing updated software, purchaspurchas-ing previously used and familiar food products, or con-tinuing to make savings in a current investment fund. In each period, clients have to make repeated decisions as to whether to continue using the current product or change to another one. In this decision making process, customers take into account both _________________________

*Warsaw School of Economics, Institute of Econometrics, al. Niepodległości 162, 02-554 Warsaw, Poland, e-mail addresses: mz35109@sgh.waw.pl, bkamins@sgh.waw.pl

(2)

jective factors such as price, as well as subjective ones such as an individual’s percep-tion of product quality. Still, these are not the only determinants of such a decision. Studies suggest that customers have a significant tendency to maintain the status quo and continue their previous consumption of a product, even though another product might be objectively better [14]. The strength of this attachment to a previously used product is measured by the so called switching cost.

Switching cost is the measure of customers’ aversion to changing a currently used product for another one. Switching costs may have several causes: cognitive, transac-tional, contractual obligations to the provider, legal, behavioral, and/or related to the risk of using a new unknown product. These cognitive reasons are associated with the knowledge which has to be acquired by a customer to use a new product, e.g. users of specific software or operating system who decide to switch, must bear the cost of learning to use the new software. Transactional causes of switching costs are associated with the need to terminate the contract with the current provider and sign a new contract with an-other – this could mean monetary charges and non-monetary costs, e.g. time spent on car-rying out formalities, as well as legal consequences. On the other hand, companies often deliberately create switching costs by offering their current customers more favorable conditions. Such actions may include customer loyalty programs at gas stations or pro-grams to collect air miles offered by airlines. Also, mobile phone operators offer favorable conditions to some of their existing customers by introducing retention programs, in order to discourage these clients from switching. This reasoning is justified by the fact that the cost of acquiring a new client in the telecommunications market is 5–8 times higher than the cost of retaining a current customer [8, 23]. Another factor increasing switching costs is the risk of dissatisfaction with a new product, about which initial knowledge is limited [15]. In addition, behavioral economics literature documents a well-known

status quo bias, which is the tendency to remain at default settings and options

pro-posed by the designers of a system [2, 4, 5, 10, 14, 18].

The subject of switching cost in oligopoly markets was investigated by [25], where the effect of switching cost on price is examined with companies having vari-ous lengths of planning horizon. They show that the length of planning horizon is cru-cial in determining whether switching costs increase or decrease the market price in an oligopoly market. If companies have an infinite planning horizon, i.e. they are driven by the stationary market share distribution, an increase in switching costs decreases the market price. On the other hand, for companies with short-term business planning, such as one period ahead, the impact of switching costs on the market price is the re-verse. In this paper, we additionally investigate price dynamics, not only their long term level.

Also [6] demonstrates that switching costs raise the market price in the case of tel-ecommunication companies with short-term planning. In addition, they investigate the influence of customers’ rationality on the market price. They show that this impact depends on the level of switching costs. For low switching costs, an increase in

(3)

cus-tomers’ rationality lowers the market price. On the other hand, for high switching costs, an increase in customers’ rationality surprisingly raises the market price.

The fact that switching costs lower the level of competition in the case of compa-nies with a short-term planning horizon is confirmed by other authors [1, 7, 11]. Under certain conditions, concerning the discount factor, this relationship also holds in [22].

Furthermore, we assume that customers exhibit bounded rationality [3]. There are two sources of bounded rationality, which we include in our approach to model cus-tomers’ behavior: random errors in choosing the cheapest product due to cuscus-tomers’ imperfect perception of the price and customers’ myopia. The former of these sources is the difficulty of accurately perceiving the price. This follows from the fact that products offered by companies are often bundled, i.e. multiproduct goods. The exact composition of a product is constructed by each client. These products are priced ac-cording to complex price lists that hinder customers’ ability to compare the offers of competitors with each other. Moreover, companies often deliberately make these comparisons more difficult by applying so-called price obfuscation [9]. Customers who are not able to evaluate the real cost of a product (which also may be due to un-certain demand, e.g. the number of calls a client will make in mobile networks is not known beforehand), make random errors in the estimation of purchase costs. In our study, we incorporate this type of bounded rationality by introducing the probability of choosing a particular product modeled using the soft-max function [17]. The other source of bounded rationality is customer myopia. In the presence of switching costs, rational clients should predict the future price of products, since today’s purchase in-fluences future purchases through the switching cost mechanism. However, we as-sume that clients are myopic, i.e. they take into account only the present price. This is due to difficulties in predicting future prices.

The goal of this study is to examine how switching costs influence price dynamics in an oligopolistic market and how it is influenced by the quality of information about demand and the market renewal rate. This work extends the results obtained in [6, 25]. Unlike those articles, this study explores price dynamics, putting special emphasis on price dispersion and its autocorrelation, as well as on the quality of information about demand and the possibility of market renewal.

In the next section, we present the description of a model of Bertrand type compe-tition. In particular, we present: (1) a customer’s decision making process, taking into account his/her bounded rationality and switching costs, (2) formulas for the quantity function and profit function of companies, (3) an algorithm for firms’ decision mak-ing. In section 3, we present the results by illustrating the characteristics of prices, such as their average, dispersion and autocorrelation. Section 4 concludes.

We implemented simulations based on the model in the statistical programming environment GNU R [13], in which we also perform plots. All the codes are available from the authors upon request.

(4)

2. Model

We consider a population of N customers, who repeatedly take a decision to pur-chase one unit of a product from one of K available suppliers. The demand for this product is inelastic, i.e. each customer purchases exactly one unit of the product re-gardless of the prices offered by companies. However, the prices influence the clients’ choice of supplier. In each period t

{

1, ...,T

}

a proportion r of the customers are replaced by new customers.

2.1. Model of consumer choice

A client’s decision is to choose some company j out of K, i.e. j

{

1, ...,K

}

. The probability of a client choosing company j depends on the price and its competitors charge, as well as the company i the customer used in the previous period of time. In particular, it is possible that j = i. The probability that a customer using supplier i in the previous period will choose supplier j is given by the following soft-max function [17]:

[ ]

(

)

(

)

[ ]

(

)

(

)

1 exp ( , ) exp j j i ij j j K k k i k p SC s p p p SC δ Ι δ Ι ≠ − ≠ = − + = − +

(1)

where: pj – price of firm j, p–j – price vector of remaining firms other than j, δ –

cus-tomers’ price consciousness, SC – switching cost,I[condition] – indicator function of the

following form: [condition] 1, if condition is true 0, if condition is false I = ⎨⎧ ⎩ (2)

The probability sij expresses the customers’ preferences for lower prices and

at-tachment to the supplier they used in the previous period. In particular, if a customer considers changing her current provider ( j ≠ i), she adds the switching cost SC to the price pj when making a decision. The properties of the choice function (1) are

present-ed in more detail in the following paragraphs.

Firstly, the higher the price of firm i, the lower the probability of a client continuing to purchase the product from it and the higher the probability of switching, ceteris

pari-bus. Secondly, the higher the price of competing company j (j ≠ i), the lower the

(5)

Fig. 1. The probability of repeated buying from the currently used supplier sii for various values of the switching cost SC as a function of the price difference. Source: authors’ own work

Fig. 2. The probability of rebuying from the current supplier sii for various values of customers’ price consciousness δ as a function of the price difference. Source: authors’ own work

0 0 and 0 ij ij i j i j s s p p δ> ≠ ∂ ∂ ∀ ∀ > < ∂ ∂ (3)

(6)

The above relationships are depicted in Figs. 1 and 2. Both figures show that the probability of rebuying from the same supplier decreases as its price increases in comparison to its competitors.

Secondly, the function sij expresses (for SC > 0) a customers’ preference for

the supplier currently used, i.e. when two suppliers offer the same price, the probabil-ity of choosing the current supplier is higher. More specifically, the higher the switch-ing cost, the higher the likelihood of continuswitch-ing to buy from the same supplier, ceteris

paribus. This relationship is shown in Fig. 1. As we can see, the functions

correspond-ing to higher switchcorrespond-ing costs lay above those correspondcorrespond-ing to lower switchcorrespond-ing costs. The following relationship holds:

0 0 ij i j s SC δ > ≠ ∂ ∀ ∀ < ∂ (4)

The parameter SC representing the switching cost is a measure of the reluctance to change the currently used supplier. From a customer’s perception, the switching cost increases the price of a supplier currently not being used. As shown in Fig. 1, an in-crease in the switching cost moves the function describing the probability of continu-ing with the present supplier, sii,in terms of the price of the present supplier compared

to competitors to the right.

The parameter δ determines the degree of customers’ price consciousness, i.e. the ability to correctly perceive the differences in the prices offered by companies. Its influence on customer choice is depicted in Fig. 2. In particular, there are two extreme cases:

• For δ = 0, customers make totally random decisions, uninfluenced by price

dif-ferences. As a result, each supplier is used with equal probability, regardless of its price;

• As δ → ∞, customers choose the supplier with the lowest total cost, which is

the sum of price and switching cost, if any.

Summarizing the interpretation of customers’ price consciousness, one can say that the higher the value of the parameter δ, the more often cheaper suppliers are used. Figure 2 shows that an increase in the price sensitivity δ increases the absolute value of the derivative (slope) of the function sii at the point x = (pi – p–i) = 0. A high

abso-lute value of this derivative means that small changes in price cause a large change in the probability of rebuying from the current supplier sii.

The uncertainty expressed by the soft-max function in Eq. (1) can be interpreted in two ways. Firstly, the uncertainty about choosing the cheapest product might be asso-ciated with the limited ability of customers to perceive correctly the total cost of a product, which might be caused by a complex price list, often induced deliberately by the practice of price obfuscation by companies [9, 16]. Secondly, the heterogeneous

(7)

distribution of choices could be interpreted in terms of product differentiation, i.e. each client assigns a different base value to different products and as a result this heterogenei-ty in tastes is translated into heterogeneiheterogenei-ty of brand choice [19, 20]. Another possible approach to modeling the customer decision making process, besides using the soft-max function, is to assign to each customer an individual random utility value θi for each

brand i and diminish it by its price pi. Using such an approach, the surplus of product i

is expressed as:

i i i

s = − (5) θ p

A client chooses the product with the highest surplus:

{: 0}

choice arg max

i i

i ss

= (6)

This approach is taken in [12, 24]. These formulas would then have to be extended to incorporate a switching cost.

Let us move on to a description of the structure of the consumer population. We assume that a proportion r of the customers are replaced by newcomers in each period. For these new customers, who have not previously used any supplier, the switching cost equals zero (SC = 0). The probability of choosing supplier j is as follows:

(

)

1 exp( ) ( , ) : ( , , 0) exp j j j j ij j j K k k p s p p s p p SC p δ δ − − = − = = = −

(7)

2.2. Model of a company’s behavior

Our model considers two scenarios describing how companies can use predictions of demand: (1) the use of perfect information about the true demand function and (2) estimates resulting from conducted market research.

In the former case, companies endowed with perfect information, they know the customers’ decision making process exactly, and forecast the quantity sold in an unbiased and exact manner. Given the current volume of clients belonging to each company, they are able to calculate an unbiased expected quantity sold in the next period t:

(

)

1

(

)

1 , K , t t j j j i ij j j i q p p q s p p− − − =

(8)

(8)

Having this expected quantity, firm j can calculate its expected profit at time t:

(

,

)

(

,

)(

)

t t

j p pj j q p pj j j pj MC

π = − (9)

where: pj – price of firm j, p–j – price vector of remaining firms other than j,

MC – marginal cost.

In the latter case, firms do not possess perfect information and conduct market re-search on a small sample of customers, in order to try to infer customers’ behavior. Given this estimation procedure, companies set an optimal price. The estimated quan-tity sold by firm j is given by the following random variable:

(

)

1

(

)

1 1 , , i i q K t j j j ij j j i n Q p p s p p − − − = = =

∑∑

(10) where:

(

)

(

)

1, with probability , 0, with probability 1 , ij j j ij ij j j s p p s s p p − − ⎧⎪ = ⎨ − ⎪⎩ (11)

As a result, the profit of firm j is a random variable as well:

(

,

)

(

,

)(

)

t t

j p pj j Q p pj j j pj MC

Π = − (12)

Having specified the objective functions of the companies as a profit function, each company with probability ρ sets a price in period t, t

{

1, ...,T

}

that maximizes profits under the assumption that competitors will continue with the same prices as in the period before. This decision making process is called best-response [21].

Firms change their price by a multiple of the parameter Δ, for instance prices in UK are multiples of one penny. The parameter m specifies the maximum multiplici-ty, e.g. m = 10 means that in any period a company cannot change its price by more than 10Δ, i.e. by no more than 10 pence. This ensures that companies do not introduce large changes in prices, which is also observed in reality. Consequently, a new price pt

is selected from the discrete decision set:

{

1 , ..., 1 , 1, 1 , ..., 1

}

t t t t t t

(9)

The implementation of the described price setting mechanism is explained with the use of pseudo-code in Table 1.

Table 1. SetPrice procedure

Function SetPrice(pj, p–j, PI, Δ, m) BestProfit := -∞

For each iÎ -m, -m+1,..., 0,..., m-1, m { } If(PI = TRUE) then

newProfit := πj(pj + iΔ, p–j)

else

newProfit := Πj(pj + iΔ, p–j)

End If

If (newProfit > bestProfit) then bestProfit := newProfit bestPrice := pj + iΔ

End If End For each Return bestPrice End Function

Source: authors’ own work.

Because the model described in this section is complex (it includes a consumer choice function, procedure for estimating demand, price setting mechanism), we apply simulation to investigate its properties. The parameters used and their ranges of varia-tion in the simulavaria-tions are shown in Table 2.

The choice of the investigated ranges of parameter values is dictated by both the research problem in question and computational constraints. We employ the experimental design of grid search, thus the number of simulations to be run grows exponentially with the number of parameters investigated. Because of this, we perform a sensitivity analysis with regard only to those parameters that are crucial in answering our research questions. As a result, we do not investigate the impact of the following pa-rameters: customers’ price consciousness δ, as it is investigated in [6, 25], the marginal cost MC, since it is of little interest, as it enters the formula for the equilibrium price addi-tively and is investigated in [25], the number of customers N is a measure of demand certainty, since the lower the market research sample size N is the higher the demand un-certainty. Because the impact of demand uncertainty is captured and investigated by the regime type parameter PI, we do not assess any further the impact of N. It is worth notic-ing that when the regime type parameter PI is set to TRUE, i.e. under the perfect infor-mation regime, this is equivalent to the number of customers surveyed going to infinity, i.e. N → ∞. The parameters that are investigated are discussed below.

(10)

Table 2. Parameters of the model and their values

Parameter Values Meaning

Customers

SC [0, 3] Customers’ switching cost

δ {2} Customers’ price consciousness Firms

MC {1} Marginal cost

ρ {10%, 100%} Probability of setting a new price

PI {TRUE, FALSE} The regime of Perfect Information

Δ {0.01, 0.1} Minimal price change

m {100, 500} Maximum multiplicity of price change Oligopoly market

N {1000} Number of customers

K {2, 3} Number of firms

r [0%, 25%] Market renewal rate Technical parameters

T {40, 2000, 5000} Number of periods simulated Tburn-in {10, 100, 1000} Number of burn-in periods

Source: authors’ own work.

The range of the switching cost parameter SC is from 0 to 3. The minimum value of 0 is an evident benchmark scenario for a market with no switching costs. The max-imum value of 3 corresponds to a switching cost equal to three times the marginal cost, i.e. MC = 1. The range between 0 and 3 was also investigated in [6, 25] which makes our analysis comparable to those papers. Also, in [6, 25] we investigated the case in which companies immediately adjust their prices to opponents’ moves, which corresponds to the parameter describing the probability of setting a new price ρ being equal to 100%. In this research, we also examine the case in which companies exhibit some delay in the adjusting process by setting the probability of setting a new price ρ to be equal to 10%.

The choice of m and Δ is dictated by constraints on computational burden. The parameter Δ is the minimal price change allowed to companies and determines the precision of the price equilibrium derived, so we would like to have Δ as small as possible. The parameter m is the maximum multiplicity of the price change Δ and it increases the number of simulations to be performed and therefore the computational burden, so we would like to have m small. On the other hand, both Δ and m define the width of the price space covered, which is the product 2mΔ and we would like this to be large. Summarizing, high precision requires small Δ and small computational bur-den requires small m, but high coverage of the price set requires large 2mΔ. Therefore,

(11)

based on our needs we employ two pairs of (Δ, m), i.e. Δ = 0.01, m = 500 and Δ = 0.1, m = 100 which result in the width of price set coverage being equal to 10 and 20, respectively.

Finally, in order to determine the influence of the market renewal rate, we perform a sensitivity analysis based on the parameter r by sampling its values from the range of 0% to 25%. The maximum value of 25% is dictated by the fact that for the mature and saturated markets that we consider, the renewal rate should not exceed 25%.

The technical parameters T and Tburn-in are selected based on trial and error

depend-ing on each application of the model, so that the required summary statistics are pre-cisely calculated and stable.

3. Results of the simulations

The following section presents the characteristics of price patterns in an oligopo-listic market. Especially, we focus on the following characteristics of prices: average, dispersion and autocorrelation. We also examine the market shares of companies.

Fig. 3. The impact of the switching cost on price level and dispersion in regimes of perfect information and market research

or the following remaining parameter values: δ = 2, MC = 1, ρ = 0.1, Δ = 0.01, m = 500, N = 1000, K = 3, r = 0%, T = 5000, Tburn-in = 100. Source: authors’ own work

Figure 3 depicts the relationship between the market price and switching cost for the two regimes considered: perfect information, and uncertain demand, which

(12)

might be estimated by conducting market research. We can observe that a higher switching cost results in higher prices. This result is consistent with previous re-search on companies with a short planning horizon [1, 6, 7, 11, 25]. Under certain conditions concerning the discount factor, this result is also consistent with [22]. The slope of the average price line (both for the regime of perfect information and uncertainty) in Fig. 3 is approximately equal to 1, which means that the switching cost is fully internalized into the price. As a result, although clients want to avoid incurring switching costs by their implicit loyalty to a specific brand, they actually incur this cost each time they buy the product, as they pay a higher price. Companies are aware of the presence of switching costs and exploit this fact in the following manner. Companies that have a certain customer base could increase their price by the level of the switching cost without any fear of losing customers. As a result, customers pay more. Lower switching costs or customers behaving as if there were no switching costs would result in lower prices in the market. However, from an individual customer’s point of view, it is optimal to minimize all costs, including the switching cost. Hence, this problem is analogous to the prisoner’s dilemma [21].

In addition, Figure 3 shows that prices are higher under the regime of uncertain demand than under the regime of perfect information, ceteris paribus. These price differences are statistically significant (p-value < 0.001). Finally, we can observe in Fig. 3 that higher switching costs result in a greater dispersion of prices. For small values of the switching cost (SC ≤ 1), price dispersion is driven mostly by the uncer-tainty in estimating demand. For higher values of the switching cost (SC > 1), price dispersion grows rapidly and is smaller under the regime of perfect information than under uncertain demand.

The price dispersion is the result of switching costs, since switching costs make the optimal price dependent on the market share being stochastic. Customers move partially at random between various brands. These customer flows are described by a transition matrix [25]. Therefore, various market shares result in different behaviors by the companies, depending on whether it is beneficial to the company to attract new customers or to exploit old ones. In summary, the presence of switching costs and random customer flows between brands is a sufficient condition for price dispersion, regardless of the quality of available information, i.e. whether it is a perfect infor-mation regime or uncertain demand regime.

The decision making of firms under the regime of uncertain demand is prone to random errors in setting the optimal price. As we can see in Fig. 4, the profit function is convex and flat around the maximum point. Therefore, a small error in the estimation of the objective function results in a random price around the optimal value.

In summary, based on Figs. 3 and 4, we conclude that either positive switching costs or uncertainty in the estimation of the profit function are sufficient conditions for

(13)

the presence of price dispersion in the market. However, it should be noted that switching costs have a greater influence on the level of dispersion.

Fig. 4. Profit function of firm 1 when its competitor’s price equals 3.5, market share equals 50% for the following remaining parameter

values: SC = 1, δ = 2, MC = 1, K = 2, r = 0%. Source: authors’ own work

Figure 5 depicts the dynamics of prices and market shares for various values of the switching cost, i.e. SC

{

0,1, 2

}

, under the regime of perfect information, i.e.

PI = TRUE. This shows how the switching cost induces price dispersion. We can

observe in the top-left plot that when there is no switching cost (SC = 0), the price is constant. This is due to the fact that in the absence of a switching cost, companies do not possess any locked-in customers and consequently they compete more for both new and current customers by offering competitive prices. As a result, the market share from the previous period does not have any impact on the current price. This is observed in the bottom-left plot. We can see random market shares caused by partially random flows between brands, even though the price is fixed. The equilibrium price

p* in this case is given by the following formula:

2 *

p MC

δ

= + (14)

On the other hand, even a small switching cost (SC = 1) induces a price increase, as shown in Fig. 5. This follows from the fact that companies, being aware of the switching cost incurred by clients, try to exploit their current customer base by setting

(14)

a higher price. As a result, the optimal price in a given period depends on the compa-ny's market share in the previous period. Therefore, fluctuations in market share trans-late into fluctuations in price, as seen in Fig. 5. Moreover, we can observe that in the case of a positive switching cost, market shares fluctuate in a more systematic way than with no switching cost, i.e. SC = 0.

Fig. 5. Duopoly price patterns for various values of the switching cost (SC ∈ {0, 1, 2}) for the following remaining parameter values: δ = 2, MC = 1, ρ = 100%, PI = TRUE, Δ = 0.1,

m = 100, N = 1000, K = 2, r = 10%, T = 40, Tburn-in = 10. Source: authors’ own work

In the case of a high switching cost, the price dynamics are different. As shown in Fig. 5, firms set low and high prices alternately. Consequently, market shares also change in this fashion, since the firm setting a high price loses its market share at the expense of the company which sets a low price. Such dynamics are caused by both the high switching cost and myopic companies, i.e. companies, which assume that its competitor’s price from the previous period will remain unchanged. Consequently, in order to compete for customers with a low price company, the company with a higher price has to significantly lower its price, because the existence of a switching cost makes it difficult to drag customers from an opponent and a company assumes its opponent’s price will be low in the next period. On the other hand, the company

(15)

with a lower price raises its price significantly in order to exploit its customers, be-cause due to the switching costs it thinks that customers will continue purchasing its products and it assumes that the competitor’s price will be high in the next period. As we see, a high switching cost strengthens such pricing patterns.

Summarizing, we conclude that the high switching cost, short planning-horizon of firms and the assumption that the competitors’ price remains unchanged from the pre-vious period, results in a strong dependence between the optimal price and market share (Fig. 5). Consequently, we observe alternations between high and low prices. The strength of this coordination depends on the switching cost, as shown in Fig. 5.

Figure 5 depicts how a high switching cost (SC = 2) makes companies set alter-nately high and low prices. The difference between the high and low price is a meas-ure of customer exploitation and, as it is seen in the figmeas-ure, this depends on the switching cost. A good measure of customer exploitation is the difference between the prices as perceived by a client who does not incur the switching cost, e.g. a new client to the market. The probability of a newcomer choosing supplier j, i.e. sj, is

equivalent to the probability of a client switching from any other company to compa-ny j when the switching cost is zero and is defined by Eq. (7).

Fig. 6. Influence of the switching cost on price coordination in a duopoly market with the following remaining parameter values: δ = 2, MC = 1, ρ = 10%, PI = TRUE,

Δ = 0.1, m = 100, N = 1000, K = 2, r = 10%, T = 10000. Source: authors’ own work

The measure of price coordination attachmentStrength is presented in Fig. 6 and is defined as the maximum value of sj over j (j

{

1, ...,K

}

)

(16)

{1,..., }

(

)

attachmentStrength : max= j K s p pj j, j (15) The value of attachmentStrength can be interpreted as the probability of a client

who is new to the market buying the cheapest product, since the minimum of sj over j

is associated with the company setting the lowest price.

In the case of a duopoly (K = 2), the attachmentStrength measure ranges over the interval [0.5, 1]. In the absence of price coordination and equal prices, the chances of attracting a client new to the market are the same for both companies, i.e. equal to 0.5, hence attachmentStrength = 0.5 as well. On the other hand, in the case of price coordination, one company has a greater chance of gaining a customer new to the market and so attachmentStrength is larger. Figure 6 shows that for a high switching cost (SC = 3) it is even 95%. On the other hand, a low switching cost does not cause systematic differences in companies’ prices, which is also seen for the case of SC = 1 in Fig. 5.

Fig. 7. Heat map of the average market price conditional on the switching cost (SC) and market renewal rate (r) with the following remaining parameter values:

δ = 2, MC = 1, ρ = 100%, Δ = 0.01, m = 1, N = 1000, K = 2, T = 2000,

Tburn-in = 1000. Source: authors’ own work

The switching cost increases market prices, as seen in Fig. 3 and confirmed by earlier research [6, 25]. Figure 7 confirms this dependence but also shows how it in-teracts with the variable determining the rate of market renewal, i.e. the proportion of clients who are replaced each period by new clients. We see in Fig. 7 that the higher the market renewal rate r, the less detrimental to customers is the switching cost. An

(17)

increase in the market renewal rate r decreases the market price and this effect be-comes stronger as the switching cost increases. When there is no switching cost (SC = 0), the market renewal rate has no impact on price, because new and existing clients are treated equally by companies – the contour lines in Fig. 7 are vertical for a low switching cost. For a high switching cost, the impact of the market renewal rate r on the decline in prices is clear – the lines in Fig. 7 run more horizontally. This is due to the fact that the switching cost makes it profitable to exploit clients at-tached to the company. In the case of a high percentage of newcomers r, companies compete for new customers with lower prices.

4. Conclusions

The switching cost is a measure of customers’ aversion to change a currently used product for another one. This reluctance to change might be driven by both financial reasons, such as transactional costs, and non-financial reasons, e.g. cognitive, behav-ioral or legal. The importance of switching costs has been already documented in the field of behavioral economics [2, 4, 5, 14, 18]. In this paper, we show the significance and influence of switching costs on price patterns and their dynamics in an oligopolis-tic market.

This work confirms the result that switching costs are detrimental to competition and increase market price in the case of companies with a short-term planning horizon [1, 6, 7, 11, 25]. We show that the switching cost is almost entirely internalized into the price of the product. As a result, even though customers try to avoid incurring the switching cost, which can be described as implicit loyalty, they in fact incur this switching cost each time they purchase a product. Customers behaving as if there were no switching costs would reduce the market price. However, for each client, it is indi-vidually optimal to take into account both costs: price and the potential switching cost. That is why this problem is analogous to the prisoner’s dilemma, see [21].

Moreover, we show that positive switching costs make a firm’s optimal price de-pendent on its market share from the previous period. Since market shares are stochas-tic, this leads to the randomness of prices, which we define as price dispersion. Such price dispersion is the result of the introduction of random elements into a firm’s deci-sion making process. The first possibility is a random market share, which in the case of a positive switching cost (SC > 0) translates into a random price. The second possi-bility is uncertainty in estimating the demand curve, which results in uncertainty about the objective function leading to decisions fluctuating around the optimal price.

High switching costs result in price coordination between firms. Companies set al-ternately a high price to exploit current customers and a low price to acquire new

(18)

cus-tomers. We demonstrate that the higher the switching cost the stronger this price coor-dination.

Finally, we show the importance of the market renewal rate, i.e. the proportion of cur-rent customers replaced by new ones in each period. The higher the market renewal rate, the less detrimental the effect of switching costs on competition. In the case of a high mar-ket renewal rate, companies compete for newcomers by lowering their prices.

Further research requires the thorough examination of the parameter space, in par-ticular concerning: customers’ price consciousness (δ), the number of firms (K) and the companies’ feasible set of prices (the parameters Δ and m).

Acknowledgements

Mateusz Zawisza is thankful for financial support under the project entitled: Take scholarship – for

advancement (Weź stypendium – dla rozwoju) co-financed by the European Social Fund under the Human

Capital Operational Program.

References

[1] BEGGS A.,KLEMPERER P., Multi-period competition with switching cost, Econometrica, 1992, 60,

(3), 651–666.

[2] CAMERER C.,LOEWENSTEIN G.,RABIN M., Advances in Behavioral Economics, Princeton University Press, New York 2004.

[3] COLINSK J., Why bounded rationality?, Journal of Economics Literature, 1996, 34, (2), 669–700. [4] JOHNSON E.,GOLDSTEIN D., Do defaults save lives?, Science, 2003, 302 (5649), 1338–1339.

[5] KAHNEMAN D.,KNETSCH J.,THALER R.H., Anomalies, the endowment effect, loss aversion, and

sta-tus quo bias, Journal of Economic Perspective, 1991, 5 (1), 193–206.

[6] KAMIŃSKI B.,WOJEWNIK.P.,ZAWISZA M., ANTOSIEWICZ M., Multiagent simulation of mobile

tele-communication market with operator switching cost. Proceedings of the Seventh Conference of the

European Social Simulation Association, 2011.

[7] KLEMPERER P., The competitiveness of markets with switching cost, Rand Journal of Economics,

1987, 18 (1), 138–150.

[8] KOZIENKO P.,BRODKA P.,RUTA D., The influence of customer churn and acquisition on value

dy-namics of social neighborhoods, Lectures Notes in Computer Science, 2009, 5736, 491–500.

[9] ŁATEK M.,KAMIŃSKI B., Social learning and pricing obfuscation, Lecture Notes on Economics and

Mathematical Systems, 2009, 631, 103–114.

[10] MADRIAN B.,SHEA D., The power of suggestion: inertia in 401(k) participation and savings

behav-ior, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2001, 116 (4), 1149–1187.

[11] PADILLA A.J., Revisting dynamic duopoly with consumer switching cost, Journal of Economic Theory,

1995, 67 (2), 520–530.

[12] PERLOFF J.,SALOP S., Equilibrium with product differentiation, Review of Economic Studies, 1985,

52 (1), 107–120.

[13] R Development Core Team. A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing, R Foundation for Statistical Computing, <www.R-project.org 2011>.

(19)

[14] SAMUELSON W.,ZECKHAUSER R., Status quo bias in decision making, Journal of Risk and

Uncertain-ty, 1988, 1 (1), 7–59.

[15] SCHMALENSEE R.L, Product differentiation advantages of pioneering brands, American Economic

Review, 1982, 72 (3), 349–365.

[16] SPIEGLER R., Bounded Rationality and Industrial Organization, Oxford University Press, London

2011.

[17] SUTTON R.S.,BARTO A.G., Reinforcement Learning: An Introduction, Adaptive Computation and

Machine Learning, MIT Press, Cambridge 1998.

[18] THALER R.,SUNSTEIN C., Nudge: Improving Decision about Health, Wealth and Happiness, Yale

University Press, New Haven 2008.

[19] TIROLE J., The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT Press, Cambridge 1988.

[20] VARIAN H., Microeconomic Analysis, W.W. Norton & Company, New York 1992.

[21] VEGA-REDONDO F., Economics and the Theory of Games, Cambridge University Press, London

2003.

[22] WEIZSÄCKER C.C., The costs of substitution, Econometrica, 1984, 52 (5), 1085–1116.

[23] YAN L.,MILLER D.J.,MOZER M.C.,WOLNIEWICZ R., Improving prediction of customers behaviour in

non-stationary evnironments, Proc. International Joint Conference on Neural Networks, IJCNN,

2001, 3, 2258–2263.

[24] ZAWISZA M.,KAMIŃSKI B., Oligopolistic competition in geographical regions with product

differen-tiation. Proc. 8th European Social Simulation Association Conference, Salzburger Geographische

Arbeiten, 2012, 48, 215–227.

[25] ZAWISZA M.,KAMIŃSKI B.,WITKOWSKI W., Konkurencja firm o różnym horyzoncie planowania

w modelu Bertrand z kosztem decyzji i ograniczoną świadomością cenową klientów, Prace Naukowe

Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego we Wrocławiu Zastosowania Badań Operacyjnych: Zarządzanie

pro-jektami, Decyzje finansowe, Logistyka, Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Ekonomicznego we Wrocławiu,

Cytaty

Powiązane dokumenty

tualnym, zaś to wszystko co wiąże się z przeżyciami emocjonalnymi kodeks karny określa pojęciem pobudki. Wprawdzie obowiązujący k.k. z 1932 r.) — nie rozróżnia motywu i

Глобалізація ринку освітніх послуг: регіональні особливості та інтеграційні перспективи

Wieniawski, following Transcendental etudes or Concert etudes by Liszt, whose pupil he was in Weimar, blurs the boundaries between improvisation and composition; he draws attention

Stefko Kamil (zesz.. Karol

nierównomiernie rozłożonej chłonności akustycznej (wartość współczynnika pochłaniania wynosi 0,8 dla podłogi). Pokazane wartości czasu pogłosu odnoszą się do pomieszczeń

Nie ma on jednak tego autorytetu, ja- kim cieszą się w społeczności chrześcijan Augustyn czy Hieronim, dlatego też i portret heretyka, który przedstawia, jest inny..

A review is given of recent developments in the methods to obtain statistical data on the motions of moored vessels and on the loads in the mooring system with emphasis on

You model the evolution of the stock price over the following half year using a two-period forward binomial tree.. What is the price of a six-month, $ 82-strike European put option